The Hyperglobalization of Trade and Its Future
Arvind Subramanian and Martin Kessler
Abstract
The open, rules-based trading system has delivered immense benefits—for the world, for individual countries, and for average citizens in these countries. It can continue to do so, helping today’s low-income countries make the transition to middle-income status. Three challenges must be met to preserve this system. Rich countries must sustain the social consensus in favor of open markets and globalization at a time of considerable economic uncertainty and weakness; China and other middle-income countries must remain open; and mega-regionalism must be prevented from leading to discrimination and trade conflicts. Collective action should help strengthen the institutional underpinnings of globalization. The world should move beyond the Doha Round dead to more meaningful multilateral negotiations to address emerging challenges, including possible threats from new mega-regional agreements. The rising powers, especially China, will have a key role to play in resuscitating multilateralism.
Key words:
Hyperglobalization, trading system, mega-regionalism, mega-trader, China, criss-crossing globalization, foreign direct investment
WORKING PAPER 3
JUNE 2013
Global Citizen Foundation
Phone: +41 (0) 225 18 0265
e-mail: info@gcf.ch
The Hyperglobalization of Trade and Its Future
Arvind Subramanian and Martin Kessler
1. Introduction
The post–World War II period witnessed a rapid rise in trade between nations, reminiscent of the integration that occurred before World War 1 (see WTO forthcoming; Krugman 1995). This evolution was facilitated partly by reductions in policy barriers—first in the advanced economies, under the auspices of the then General Agreement on Trade and Tariffs (GATT), and later in developing countries, through unilateral liberalization actions or under programs with the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and World Bank. Trade was also facilitated by technological advances, especially in shipping and transportation costs. By the end of the 1980s and early 1990s, global trade integration had reverted to levels last seen before World War I.
The postwar period also saw a number of growth successes, beginning with Japan (and Europe), followed by the East Asian tigers and then China and more recently by India. Along the way, a few countries in Sub-Saharan Africa and Latin America also succeeded in raising their standards of living.
In the late 1990s, however, a striking change occurred in the economic fortunes of countries: economic growth took off across the world, a phenomenon that is best described as convergence with a vengeance. Until the late 1990s, only about 30 percent of the developing world (21 of 72 countries) was catching up with the economic frontier (the United States), and the rate of catch-up was about 1.5 percent per capita per year (table 1.1).1 Since the late 1990s, nearly three-quarters of the developing world (75 of 103 countries) started catching up, at an accelerated annual pace of about 3.3 percent per capita. Although developing country growth slowed during the global financial crisis (2008–12), the rate of catch-up with advanced countries was not materially affected and remained close to 3 percent (see also Rodrik’s paper on this website).
Arvind Subramanian is a senior fellow at the Peterson Institute for International Economics and the Center for Global Development. Martin Kessler is a research analyst at the Peterson Institute. The authors are grateful to the project’s participants, including Richard Baldwin, Nancy Birdsall, Kemal Derviş, Shahrokh Fardoust, Theophilos Priovolos, Dani Rodrik, and Andrew Steer, and their colleagues at the Peterson Institute for International Economics and the Center for Global Development for helpful discussions. This paper draws on work with Aaditya Mattoo and on Subramanian (2011). This paper was prepared for the Towards a Better Global Economy Project funded by the Global Citizen Foundation. The authors alone are responsible for its content. Comments or questions should be directed to asubramanian@piie.com.
1 All growth figures in this paragraph use a GDP measure in purchasing power parity (PPP) terms.
Table 1.1 Convergence: Growth of Developing Countries Compared to with Growth in the United States
Indicator | 1870–1960 (Maddison) | 1960–2000 (Penn World Tables 7.1) | 2000–07 (Penn World Tables 7.1) | 2000–11 (World Development Indicators) | 2008–12 (World Economic Outlook) a |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
U.S. growth rate of GDP per capita (percent) | 1.7 | 2.47 | 1.28 | 0.65 | 0.02 |
World growth rate of GDP per capita (percent) | 1.3 | 2.75 | 3.17 | 2.28 | 1.73 |
Number of developing countries in which growth exceeded U.S. rate | 2 | 21 | 75 | 80 | 78 |
Percentage of developing countries in which growth exceeded U.S. rate | 5.3 | 29.2 | 72.8 | 89.9 | 83.9 |
Average excess over U.S. growth (percentage points)b | 0.02 | 1.53 | 3.25 | 2.94 | 3.03 |
Number of countries in sample | 38 | 72 | 103 | 89 | 93 |
Note: Sample excludes oil exporters (as defined by the IMF) and countries with populations of less than 1 million.
a. Based on GDP in constant dollars. Other columns use GDP in PPP terms.
b. Computed as simple average growth of countries whose growth exceeds that of the United States.
At around the same time, perhaps just preceding this convergence phase, world trade started to surge, ushering in an era of hyperglobalization. That rising globalization (hereafter used interchangeably with trade integration) is associated with stronger growth, which is a prerequisite for improving the situation of average citizens all over the world, is reason enough to seek to sustain it. This integration need not continue at the torrid pace of recent years; it should be sustained at a relatively steady rate and any serious reversal, which could set back the prospects of the average global citizen, avoided.
This paper is divided into six sections. The next section documents some of the salient features of this era of hyperglobalization. Section 3 discusses three key areas where the trading system is seen as inadequate. The problems are illustrative of the proximate challenges and possible solutions, but in important ways, they cannot be solved unless the more fundamental challenges of globalization are addressed. Section 4 explores these deeper challenges. Section 5 suggests possible policy responses at the national and international levels that could help sustain globalization. Section 6 offers brief concluding remarks.
The paper is not comprehensive: it focuses on the trade aspects of globalization. It does not discuss other important forms of globalization relating to the movement of finance and people. Rather, it focuses on the major challenges, emphasizing aspects and arguments that have perhaps received less attention thus far.2
2. Seven Important Characteristics of the Most Recent Wave of Globalization
This section describes seven major features of the current era of hyperglobalization and of today’s trading system:
- hyperglobalization (the rapid rise in trade integration)
- the dematerialization of globalization (the importance of services)
- democratic globalization (the widespread embrace of openness)
- criss-crossing globalization (the similarity of North-to-South trade and investment flows with flows in the other direction)
- the rise of a mega-trader (China), the first since Imperial Britain
- the proliferation of regional trade agreements and the imminence of mega-regional ones
- the decline of barriers to trade in goods but the continued existence of high barriers to trade in services
2 For this reason, notable features such as the decline in transportation costs and improvements in information and communication technologies, which have been widely noted, are not studied in depth here (for discussions of these issues, see WTO 2013).
Hyperglobalization
Since the early 1990s, the world has entered into an era of what might be called hyperglobalization (figure 2.1). The years between 1870 and 1914 have been described as the first golden age of globalization. World trade as a share of gross domestic product (GDP) surged from 9 percent in 1870 to 16 percent on the eve of World War I. This was the era that Keynes waxed eloquently about, noting that an inhabitant of London “could order by telephone, sipping his morning tea in bed, the various products of the whole earth, in such quantity as he might see fit, and reasonably expect their early delivery upon his doorstep” (Keynes 1920, p.11).
Figure 2.1 World Exports, in Current Dollars, 1870–2011
The period between 1914 and the end of World War II witnessed the Great Reversal of globalization, as the combustible mix of isolationism, nationalism, and militarism ignited protectionist policies. World trade plunged to a low of 5.5 percent of world GDP just before World War II began (O’Rourke and Williamson 1999; Frieden 2006; Irwin 2011).
A third era, starting after World War II, saw the restoration of world trade, aided by declines in transport costs and trade barriers. Only by about the mid- to late 1970s did world trade revert to the peaks seen before World War I.
The world is now in a fourth era, of hyperglobalization, in which world trade has soared much more rapidly than world GDP. Merchandise exports-to-GDP ratios soared from 15 percent to 26 percent, and goods and services exports to about 33 percent 3, over the course of the last two decades. This rapid increase is somewhat surprising, because transport costs do not appear to have declined as rapidly as in earlier eras (Hummels, Ishii, and Yi 2001; Baldwin 2011a). The cost of information and communications did decline significantly, however.
Part of the increase in trade reflects the fragmentation of manufacturing across borders—the famous slicing up of the value-added chain—as individual production stages are located where the costs of production are lowest. This phenomenon, whereby technology no longer requires that successive stages of manufacturing production be physically contiguous or proximate, has been dubbed the “second unbundling” (Baldwin 2011a).4
This real technological impetus to trade tends to artificially inflate recorded trade. Because value is added at each stage of the production chain, it is recorded as exports at successive links in the chain. Gross exports flows therefore overstate real flows of valued added (exports net of imported intermediate goods). Figure 2.1 shows that, even though value added–based exports of goods and services are about 5 percentage points lower than exports measured on a gross basis, their trajectory has been similar to that of conventionally measured exports. More recently, value added as a share of exports has not declined substantially or across all trading regions (Hanson 2012; WTO 2013).5
3 Throughout this paper, we use trade data as currently measured, on a gross basis. Wherever possible, and as a cross-check, we also present results for trade data measured on a value-added basis. The appendix explains how these values are calculated.
4 The first unbundling reflected in the quotation from Keynes is the separation of the producer from the consumer that increased trade permits.
5 Koopman, Wang, and Wei (2013) further refined the measurement of value-added trade by distinguishing where countries are (upstream versus downstream) in the value-added chain. The aggregate value-added measures reported here are computed as in their paper.
Figure 2.2 Stocks and Flows of Foreign Direct Investment, 1913–2011
A related feature of this era of hyperglobalization is the rise of multinational corporations and the sharp surge in flows of foreign direct investment (FDI), which have both caused and been caused by cross-border and other flows of goods and services. Since the early 1990s (broadly coinciding with the era of hyperglobalization), FDI flows have surged, growing substantially faster than GDP (figure 2.2). Global FDI as a share of world GDP, which hovered around 0.5 percent, increased sevenfold, peaking at close to 4 percent just before the onset of the recent global financial crisis. Even discounting the two surges of 1997–2000 and 2005–08, the general trend is steadily increasing. Global FDI stocks (which are less volatile than flows) jumped from less than 10 percent of GDP in the early 1990s to 30 percent in 2011. FDI flows, and stocks, now surpass levels achieved in the first golden era of globalization, before World War I. By 2009, there were more than 80,000 multinationals, accounting for about two-thirds of world trade (UNCTAD 2010).
“Dematerializing” Globalization
The rapid increase in trade has occurred in both goods and services. Based on conventional (gross) trade data, services trade represented about 17 percent of world trade in 1980 and about 20 percent in 2008. Measured in value-added terms, the corresponding numbers are 30 percent and 40 percent. The apparent paradox that we seek to explain in this section is that services trade, which represents 6 percent of world GDP in gross terms, is 40–50 percent larger when computed in value added terms. This phenomenon arises because services are not always directly tradable but are sometimes embodied in the production of goods that are traded. In traditional trade statistics, such services are not counted as traded; in value added terms, they are considered as such, because production of the service takes place in one country and consumption in another one. Traditional measures of services trade underestimate their importance in global trade.
Two underlying factors can explain the “dematerialization” of trade. First, as Johnson and Noguera (2012) show, the ratio of value-added exports to gross exports in manufacturing goods decreased in the last 30 years (from 60 percent in 1980 to 45 percent in 2009), as a result of the rising importance of global value chains in this sector. Second, as explained in the previous paragraph, trade in services is larger and growing faster in value added terms than traditional statistics show. Soon, trade in services could eclipse trade in goods, less because services are traded directly than because services are increasingly embodied in goods. Trade will actually be dematerializing—moving from “stuff” to intangibles—although the manifestation will be, and the data will record, the opposite effect.
Value added–based trade data reveal how much of total value added in a sector is traded globally. Figure 2.3 plots world exports (gross and value added) of goods as a share of world value added in goods (defined to include agriculture and industry), as well as similar numbers for services. During the period of hyperglobalization, value added exports of goods as a share of total value added in the sector (agriculture and industry) increased from about 33 percent to 47 percent, and services as a share of value added in the services sector increased from 11 percent to 16 percent. Thus, the pace at which services are becoming tradable mirrors that in merchandise.
Figure 2.3 Global Tradability of Goods and Services, 1975–2010
The slower rise in the tradability of goods than services in the era of hyperglobalization may partly reflect the differential rise in the costs of transport versus information and communications technologies (ICT). After plummeting sharply between about 1940 and 1980, transport costs appear to have stabilized (Baldwin 2011; Hummels 2007). In contrast, about 1990, the use of ICT–related technologies and applications surged. A consequence could have been a differential fillip to more sophisticated goods and especially services.
Democratic Globalization
Part of the increase in trade also reflects convergence and the wider distribution of output and income: that is, trade has grown because output has become more widespread and “democratic.” 10
Basic gravity theory implies that smaller countries tend to trade more than larger ones.6 A world of two equal-size countries will experience more trade than a world in which the larger country accounts for 95 percent of world output. Over time, the world is becoming less unequal in terms of the distribution of the underlying output that generates trade.7 For example, between 1970 and 2000 the world was constituted by about 7.0–7.5 country equivalents (with fluctuations) (figure 2.4).
Figure 2.4 Dispersion of World Output and World Exports, 1970–2010
6 The gravity model of trade is theoretically well established and empirically validated. It shows that trade between two countries is proportional to their economic size and inversely proportional to their distance. Other things equal, a large country will trade more than a small one but will be less open (trade/GDP will be smaller).
7 As Anderson (2011) shows, in a world without trade frictions, the share of trade in world output is given by 1 – Σjbj2 where bj is the share of a country in world output. Inverting the expression gives the number of country-equivalents in the world, which increases with convergence. Baier and Bergstrand (2001) find a statistically significant effect of convergence on trade.
Since 2000, as more countries have started catching up with the rich, world output has become more dispersed: today, it is as if there were 10 country-equivalents in the world. In the era of hyperglobalization, roughly a third of the increase in trade can be accounted for by this democratization of world output (figure 2.4).
Figure 2.5 Trade Openness, 1870–2010
8 We chose the openk variable because it is the most comparable with the Maddison (pre–World War II) GDP data in that both are in constant purchasing power parity dollars. For the pre-War export data, there are two options for deflation: a measure of general U.S. inflation (for example, the consumer price index [CPI]) or a measure of export prices. Maddison provides a real export series based on the latter. We chose the CPI option for the simple reason that the estimates for 1950 matched better the pre–World War II estimates for the years close to 1950. If we use Maddison’s real export data, the changes over time are even more dramatic than shown in figure 2.4 (that is, export-to-GDP ratios are lower for the past when exports are deflated by an export price index than a CPI index).
Even if the rise in world trade is caused by spreading prosperity, is this rise itself broadly spread? The numbers in figure 2.1 are in effect a GDP–weighted average of individual country’s export-to-GDP ratios. We can, instead, calculate export-to-GDP ratios that are unweighted or weighted by population to measure the reach of globalization across countries and across people, as done in figure 2.5.
Figure 2.5 shows that in 1913, the peak of the first golden era of globalization, the unweighted average export-to-GDP ratio in the world was close to 15 percent. In 2010, it was 21.5 percent. The population-weighted export-to-GDP ratio was about 6 percent; by 2010, it was 15 percent. Hyperglobalization has thus come about not just because some rich countries are becoming more open but also because openness is being embraced more widely.9 Keynes’ paean to globalization was thus both imperialist and elitist.10, 11
Criss-Crossing Globalization
Trade has been increasing steadily. But one of the unique features of the most recent phase of hyperglobalization is the fact that similar kinds of goods (and capital) are criss-crossing global borders. In other words, it is less and less the case that a country’s imports and exports are very different.
Three manifestations of such criss-crossing globalization can be discerned. In the immediate aftermath of World War II, the industrial countries increasingly started to export and import manufactured goods (for example, Japan, Germany, and the United States all exported and imported cars), a phenomenon at odds with classic Ricardian model. Models of monopolistic competition (Helpman and Krugman 1985) combined with consumers’ love for variety (differentiated products) provided the theoretical basis for the phenomenon of intraindustry trade that related to trade in final goods. Melitz and Trefler (2012) show that the share of intraindustry trade in total trade increased by nearly 20 percentage points. But this increase occurred between 1960 and the mid-1990s rather than over the most recent period of hyperglobalization. In fact, since the 1990s, this share of intraindustry trade has stabilized (Brulhart 2008).
9 One potential problem with figure 2.5 is that the sample is not constant over time. The finding that trade has become more democratized holds even for the constant sample of countries (not reported here). The unweighted average is above the population-weighted average because populous countries tend to trade less.
10 Even within the United Kingdom, the benefits of globalization were not broadly accessible. In 1912, for example, there were 0.6 million telephone subscribers in the United Kingdom, the population of which was about 46 million.
11 Another way of describing this democratization is to note that the trade of low- and middle-income countries has grown more rapidly than their incomes and more rapidly than the trade of high-income countries and that a bulk of this growth is trade among low- and middle-income countries (Hanson 2012).
For the rapidly growing emerging market countries of Asia, criss-crossing globalization has taken the form of greater two-way flows of parts and components than of final goods. This phenomenon is related to the slicing up of the value-added chain and the unbundling noted above.
The share of parts and components in trade offers one measure of criss-crossing globalization. For the world as a whole, this share increased from about 22 percent in 1980 to 29 percent in 2000. Since then, intermediate goods trade declined to about 26 percent of total trade, suggesting that the internationalization of production may have peaked (WTO 2013). Indeed, this form of globalization was really observed only in Asia, and even there intermediate trade has declined since 2000. Even in China, reliance on imports has declined markedly. In the computer sector (broadly defined), for example, exports were only 1.6 times imports in 1994, indicating substantial intermediate trade; by 2008, this ratio had climbed to 4.2 (Hanson 2012).
The third (and perhaps least remarked on) dimension of criss-crossing globalization, with potentially important effects for globalization policies, relates to two-way flows of FDI. It is one of the unique aspects of this era of hyperglobalization that developing countries (especially the larger ones) are exporting FDI (which embodies sophisticated factors of production, including entrepreneurial and managerial skills and technology)—and not just to other developing or countries (Mattoo and Subramanian 2010). Figure 2.6 plots a Grubel-Lloyd index of two-way flows of FDI at the global level.12 Depending on the weighting, this index climbed from about 0.3 in 1970 to almost 0.7 by 2011.
Figure 2.6 Two-Way Foreign Direct Investment Flows, 1970–2011
The Rise of a Genuine Mega-Trader: China
When Krugman (1995) surveyed the evolution of world trade, he noted as one of the distinctive features the rise of a number of Asian super-traders, including Singapore, Hong Kong (China), and Malaysia, all of whose exports exceeded 50 percent of GDP, a feature never seen in the first era of globalization (in 1913, the United Kingdom’s ratio of export to GDP was 18.5 percent). But mega-traders can be defined in two senses: globally (relative to world trade) and nationally (relative to a country’s own output). Krugman clearly applied the latter criterion. Had he applied the former, one mega-trader he would have identified would have been Japan in the 1980s, which accounted for about 7.5 percent of global trade at its peak. Based on this criterion, none of the other East Asian Tigers would have been noteworthy, despite their astonishing performance: the small economies of Singapore, Hong Kong (China), Taiwan (China), and Malaysia accounted for a very small share of world trade at their peaks.
12 The Grubel-Lloyd index, which can take values between 0 and 1, measures the degree of two-way flows for a given country or industry. An index of 0 denotes that a country’s exports and imports are perfectly dissimilar—that is, a country is either fully an importer or an exporter of a good (or, in this specific case, a type of capital flow). An index of 1 denotes that a country’s exports and imports are similar—that is, a country exports and imports of a certain good are identical in magnitude.
Since 1990, a true mega-trader has emerged, China. It qualifies as such under both definitions of the term. Its integration into world trade accelerated with its accession to the WTO in 2001, transforming it into the world’s largest exporter and importer of manufactured goods, having surpassed the United States in 2012 (table 2.2).
Table 2.2 Merchandise Exports as Share of World Exports by Mega-Traders, 1870–2030
(percent)
(percent) Year | United Kingdom | Germany | United States | Japan | China |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
1870 | 24.3 | 13.4 | 5.0 | 0.1 | 2.8 |
1913 | 18.5 | 18.0 | 9.0 | 0.8 | 2.0 |
1929 | 15.1 | 16.6 | 14.4 | 2.1 | 3.0 |
1950 | 10.2 | 3.9 | 16.2 | 1.3 | 0.9 |
1973 | 5.1 | 12.9 | 12.2 | 6.4 | 1.0 |
1990 | 5.3 | 12.0 | 11.3 | 8.2 | 1.8 |
2000 | 4.4 | 8.5 | 12.1 | 7.4 | 3.9 |
2012 | 2.6 | 7.7 | 8.4 | 4.4 | 11.2 |
2020 (projected) | 1.9 | 5.3 | 8.8 | 3.9 | 12.1 |
2030 (projected) | 1.4 | 3.6 | 7.3 | 3.2 | 15.0 |
China’s exports as a share of GDP are now almost 50 percent. When its size and income level are taken into account, it is a substantial over-trader, comparable to the United Kingdom in the heyday of its empire and a vastly bigger trader than the United States, Japan, or Germany at their peaks.
For example, in 1975, the United States’ trade-to-GDP ratio was 13.3 percent (table 2.3). Given the size and income level of the United States, that number represented under-trading of about 50 percent. Japan in 1990, with a trade-to-GDP ratio of 20 percent, under-traded by about 50 percent. In contrast, China’s trade-to-GDP ratio in 2008 was 56.5 percent, which represented over-trading of nearly 75 percent. Only Imperial Britain was a mega-trader in both senses of the term. In 1913, its exports represented 18.5 percent of world exports. Its export-to-GDP ratio was 12 percent, which represented over-trading of about 84 percent. China is thus the first mega-trader since Imperial Britain.
Table 2.3 Exports and Imports as Percent of GDP in Selected Mega-Traders
(trade as percent of GDP) Percent over-trading, controlling for key gravity variables
Item | Actual | Controlling for size | Controlling for size and income level | Controlling for size, income level, and oil-based economies |
---|---|---|---|---|
United Kingdom 1870 (sample includes 26 countries) | ||||
Exports | 12.2 | 339.3*** | 84.0* | n.a |
United States 1975 (sample includes 121 countries) | ||||
Exports | 8.5 | –9.5 | –37.0*** | –36.3*** |
Imports | 7.6 | –30.5*** | –37.7*** | –37.5*** |
Total trade (exports + imports) | 16.1 | –20.9*** | –35.5*** | –35.1*** |
Japan 1990 (sample includes 131 countries) | ||||
Exports | 10.3 | –33.8*** | –56.8*** | –55.6*** |
Imports | 9.4 | –44.3*** | –49.4*** | –51.4** |
Total trade (exports + imports) | 19.7 | –40.4*** | –52.9*** | –53.7*** |
China 2008 (sample = 136 countries) | ||||
Exports | 35.0 | 79.9*** | 68.6** | 80.5*** |
Imports | 27.3 | 45.7*** | 46.2*** | 38.0** |
Total trade (exports + imports) | 62.2 | 64.6*** | 60.8*** | 62.0*** |
Sources: Maddison for United Kingdom; IMF various years and Penn World Table 7.1 for all other countries.
Note: All coefficients were obtained by running a regression of exports, imports, trade on column heads a plus dummy for the country in question. The level of over-/under trading is exp(dummy coefficient) – 1. A negative value denotes under-trading. * = significant at the 10 percent level, ** = significant at the 5 percent level, *** = significant at the 1 percent level.
If trade continues to grow in line with income, China’s dominance in world trade will become even greater. According to simple calculations in Subramanian (2011), by 2030 China could account for about 16–17 percent of world exports, nearly three times the share of the United States (see table 2.2).13 Even at the height of U.S. dominance, around 1975, it did not account for as large a share of world trade or have as great an edge over its nearest competitors (in 2000, the United States accounted for about 16 percent of world exports compared with 8 percent for Germany and about 7 percent for Japan). Any discussion of trade and the trading system going forward must recognize this development (discussed further below).
Growing Regionalization, Preferential Trade, and Impending Hyperregionalization
The era of hyperglobalization has been accompanied by a proliferation of preferential trade agreements (PTAs). Today, about half of the exports of the top 30 exporters go to preferential trade partners. Between 1990 and 2010, the number of PTAs increased from 70 to 300 (figure 2.7). In the mid-1990s, about 75 percent of PTAs were regional; by 2003, this share had dropped to about 50 percent. All World Trade Organization (WTO) members except Mongolia have concluded at least one PTA; some, such as the European Union, Chile, and Mexico, have concluded more than 20. Some of the large traders have already concluded agreements with each other or are about to do so (examples include the European Union and Mercosul, Japan and Mercosul, the European Union and India, and India and Japan).
The fact that nearly half of world trade is covered by preferential agreements does not mean that a comparable figure enjoys preferential barrier reductions. Carpenter and Lendle (2010) estimates that only about 17 percent of world trade is eligible for preferences; the remaining 83 percent either enjoys zero nondiscriminatory tariffs (nearly 50 percent) or is excluded from preferential agreements. Moreover, where preferences can apply, margins are low. For example, less than 2 percent of world imports enjoy preferences greater than 10 percentage points.
13 The WTO (2013) projection for 2035 is exactly in line with the estimate in Subramanian (2011). The WTO’s mean estimate is that China will account for 17 percent of world trade in 2035, with a range of 11–23 percent.
Figure 2.7 Number of New Signed Preferential Trade Agreements, 1958–2012
An interesting new dimension of these PTAs is the extent to which they feature “deep integration” (Lawrence 1996)—that is, liberalize not only tariffs and quotas but other “behind-the-border” barriers, such as regulations and standards, as well. In the last 10 years, for example, nearly 40 agreements have included provisions on WTO–Plus issues (competition policy, intellectual property rights, investment, and the movement of capital). This figure is four to five times greater than comparable agreements in the pre–WTO era (WTO 2011) (see figure 2.7 and table 2.4).
In part because of these deep integration agreements, it would be wrong on the basis of the tariff evidence to underestimate the potential discriminatory effect of preferential arrangements. In agriculture and some manufacturing sectors, such as textiles, tariffs are still high. In services, any future deepening of preferential agreements could create significant discrimination against outsiders, because most favored nation (MFN) levels of protection are significant and there is considerable scope for the preferential recognition of standards, licensing, and qualification requirements. Strong exclusionary effects could also arise from “deeper integration” along other dimensions: preferential agreements increasingly have provisions on investment protection, intellectual property rights, government procurement, competition policy, and technical barriers to trade. A discriminatory tariff may matter less than the selective recognition of product safety standards or selective access to government procurement markets.
Table 2.4 Number and Type of Preferential Trade Agreements
Type of agreement | Pre–WTO | 1995–2000 | Post-2000 |
---|---|---|---|
WTO+ issues | |||
Customs | 13 | 11 | 56 |
Antidumping | 12 | 8 | 53 |
Countervailing measures | 4 | 5 | 52 |
Export taxes | 8 | 8 | 41 |
State aid | 10 | 9 | 34 |
Trade-related intellectual property rights | 6 | 4 | 41 |
Services | 7 | 2 | 39 |
State trading enterprises | 5 | 3 | 35 |
Technical barriers to trade | 2 | 2 | 36 |
Sanitary and phytosanitary standards | 2 | 1 | 35 |
Public procurement | 5 | 0 | 32 |
Trade-related investment measures | 6 | 2 | 31 |
WTO plus X issues | |||
Competition policy | 11 | 9 | 19 |
Movement of capital | 6 | 5 | 38 |
Intellectual property rights | 5 | 2 | 39 |
Investment | 4 | 1 | 35 |
Source: Baldwin 2011b.
Note: WTO+ provisions concern commitments that already exist in WTO agreements but go beyond the WTO disciplines. WTOX provisions cover obligations that are outside the current WTO aegis.
On regional agreements, seismic changes are under way, with the possible negotiation of mega-regional agreements between the United States and Asia (the Trans-Pacific Partnership) and the United States and Europe (the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership). Trade between these groups of countries accounts for about $2–$3 trillion a year in world trade, signifying a potentially major jump in the volume of trade covered by preferential agreements. These PTAs would represent the first between the top four major regions of the world (China, the United States, Europe, and Japan), with consequences that will be discussed below. If the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership and Trans-Pacific Partnership (to the extent that it includes Japan) are concluded, more than half of global trade will be covered by those deeper regional agreements. It is not unforeseeable to think of an era in which nearly all trade becomes regional.
Lower Formal Barriers in Goods, High Barriers in Services
The world has become much less protectionist. Globally, MFN tariffs have declined from more than 25 percent in the mid-1980s to about 8 percent today. Border barriers (tariffs and nontariff measures) in manufacturing in the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries are less than 4 percent.
Figure 2.8 Average Most Favored Nation Tariffs by Income Group, 1981–2009
The U.S. International Trade Commission (USITC 2011) estimates that the welfare gains in the United States from eliminating all remaining tariffs are close to zero. Border barriers in the larger emerging markets are higher, but they have declined considerably, from about 45 percent in the early 1980s to just over 10 percent in 2009 (figure 2.8). But barriers to trade in services remain high.14 Borchert, Gootiz, and Mattoo (2012) calculate restrictiveness trade indexes for services. They cover five major sectors—financial services, telecommunications, retail distribution, transport and professional services—and the different modes of delivering these services across borders cross-border and via investment abroad). The index ranges from 0 (completely free) to 100 (completely restricted). Barriers vary across service sectors, but the average level is high (figure 2.9). 15 Barriers are relatively low in telecommunications and relatively high in transportation and professional services. They also vary across regions: Latin America is nearly as open as OECD countries, whereas Asia and the Middle East have high barriers. In fact, as in goods, barriers are correlated with a country’s level of development (figure 2.1). What this means is that international negotiations will increasingly focus on services and FDI.
Figure 2.9 Index of Services Trade Restrictiveness, by Sector and Region, 2008–10
14 There are no data on barriers to trade in services going back in time that would allow a quantitative description of changes in barriers.
15 This index cannot strictly be compared with tariffs, but the farther away the number is from zero, the less open a country is.
Figure 2.10 Index of Services Trade Restrictiveness and per Capita GDP
Two points are worth noting. First, barriers to trade in goods and services have declined sharply over time; the world as a whole is thus becoming less closed. But the composition of world trade is shifting toward the poorer countries (especially toward China and India), and these countries are on average more protectionist (as figures 2.8–2.10 illustrate). The composition of world output is also shifting toward services and away from manufacturing. Both these compositional shifts make the world as a whole less open and attenuate the liberalization trend that stems from all countries reducing barriers.
Second, the integration of goods and services markets is nowhere close to completion. One way of assessing how far from full globalization the world still is might be to compare actual trade with what is predicted by a simple gravity model without frictions. As Krugman (1995) and Anderson (2011) show, under frictionless trade, the world trade share is inversely related to the distribution of GDP across countries: the more equal the distribution, the greater the world trade share. In 1970, actual trade was about 10 percent of the theoretical maximum predicted by the frictionless gravity model. In 2011, it was about 40 percent (perhaps less if trade is calculated on a value-added basis). Thus, although actual trade is rapidly catching up with trade in a frictionless world, there is still some way to go.16
3. Three Pressing Proximate Challenges
This section discusses three recent challenges that have emerged in the trading system and proposes potential solutions to each of them. The proposed solutions can never be reached on their own, however, unless the deeper and more fundamental challenges, discussed in subsequent sections, are addressed.17
Trade and Currency Wars
Mercantilism and self-insurance: The dual origins of reserve accumulation
In the late 1990s, in the aftermath of the Asian financial crisis, a number of emerging market countries, especially in Asia, adopted an economic strategy that was dubbed Bretton Woods II (Dooley, Folkerts-Landau, and Garber 2003). This strategy had two motivations and one manifestation. Reeling from the disruption that sudden withdrawal of foreign capital had caused to their economies and chafing at the political humiliation of having to borrow from the IMF, they decided to self-insure against future crises.18 Self-insurance took the form of building an arsenal of foreign exchange reserves (see the paper by Allen and others on this website; Goldstein 2009). The second motivation was mercantilism, a strategy that made trade surplus the engine of growth.
Both motivations translated into a common manifestation: countries moved from being large net importers of finance (running large current account deficits) to being less reliant on finance, or in some cases, notably China, Malaysia, and Taiwan (China), to becoming net exporters of finance (running current account surpluses). These motivations also translated into—actually require—a policy of undervaluing the exchange rate in a fixed or managed peg regime, aided by intervention in foreign exchange markets. A few countries in East Asia (China and Malaysia in particular) tended to maintain restrictions on capital inflows as a way of sustaining a competitive exchange rate.
16 An implication of this finding on unrealized globalization is that going forward, this potential is likely to be greater in services than in goods.
17 The next section, on trade and currency wars, draws on Mattoo and Subramanian (2009).
18 The perceived humiliation was captured in the picture of the IMF Managing Director at the time, Michel Camdessus, looking over a head-bent President Suharto signing the economic adjustment program with the IMF.
Bergsten and Gagnon (2012, p. 2) argue that more than 20 countries have been intervening in foreign exchange markets for several years “at an average rate of nearly $1 trillion annually… to keep their currencies undervalued and thus boost their international competitiveness and trade surpluses.” These countries include China and a number of East Asian countries, oil exporters, and some advanced countries, including Israel and Switzerland.
This problem is not new. Similar issues of undervaluation arose relating to the Deutsche mark in the 1960s and the yen in the 1970s and 1980s. The mercantilism or currency wars of today are related to the much deeper problem—and some would argue the greatest design flaw in the Bretton Woods system—of the asymmetric adjustment between surplus and deficit countries in the international monetary and trade system. Bergsten and Gagnon (2012, p. 10)) write that “it is a huge irony that the Bretton Woods system was created at the end of the Second World War primarily to avoid repeating the disastrous experiences of the inter-war period with competitive devaluations, which led to currency wars and trade wars that in turn contributed importantly to the Great Depression, but that the system has failed to do so.”
Consequences of mercantilism
Why are current account surpluses combined with undervalued exchange rates a problem for the international economic system? The consequences or problems can be categorized as cyclical mercantilism, structural mercantilism, and macro-mercantilism.
Cyclical mercantilism arises when the economy is depressed relative to trend growth; such a situation is characterized by idle resources, underutilized capital, and unemployment. Mercantilism by one country threatens deflation in partner countries facing idle resources. This concern preoccupied Keynes, who argued that because of international liquidity constraints, there would always be greater pressure on debtors (countries running deficits) to adjust than on creditors. This asymmetry would impart a deflationary bias, because debtor countries would have to cut demand without surplus countries having to undertake the offsetting reflation. He therefore proposed that pressure be exerted on creditor countries by forcing them to pay instead of receiving interest on their positive balances (see Williamson 2010).
In the current context, the deflationary impact of Chinese policies on the United States, quantified by Cline (2010), has prompted some commentators to call for aggressive trade action by the United States against China and other countries practicing mercantilism (Krugman 2010; Bergsten and Gagnon 2012). Persistent surpluses by Germany and their deflationary impact, especially within Europe, have sparked similar calls for action (Wolf 2010).
Structural mercantilism arises when a country pursues policies such as undervalued exchange rates as development or growth policy for an extended period of time. Such policies can have long-run effects on partner countries. An undervalued exchange rate is both an import tax and an export subsidy; it can have adverse effects on trading partners. One way structural mercantilism is transmitted is by depressing the medium-run price of manufactured products, reducing opportunities for specialization in manufacturing and manufactured exports in partner countries. The concerns expressed in Sub-Saharan Africa and Latin America relate to structural mercantilism. Mattoo, Mishra, and Subramanian (2012) show, for example, that a 10 percent depreciation of China’s real exchange rate reduces a developing country’s exports of a typical product to third markets by about 1.5–2.0 percent. Such a decline can have long-run growth effects.
Macro-mercantilism was most evident in the recent crisis in the creation of the so-called savings glut (Bernanke 2005, 2007). Large and growing aggregate current account surpluses increase global liquidity, leading to easy credit and lending, which can easily morph into imprudence, financial excess, and asset bubbles, threatening financial stability. The savings glut hypothesis is by no means uncontested; many economists argue that monetary and regulatory policies in borrowing countries should bear the brunt of responsibility (Johnson and Kwak 2010; Haldane 2010). How much blame the bartender should bear for plying alcohol on a drinker who binges will forever be disputed. But that excess liquidity was a factor and that Chinese mercantilist policies created excess liquidity are plausible deeper causes of the Lehman crisis (see Bernanke and others 2011).
Currency wars or the resulting global imbalances are a systemic problem only if one or a few large countries pursue them. The possibility of collective action to prevent them must take account of this reality.
Exchange rates and foreign exchange intervention are centrally implicated in mercantilism. The international monetary system, under the auspices of the IMF, is therefore the best forum in which to find a solution. The prospects for any serious reform remain slim, however, because of the inherent limits to international monetary cooperation. Systemic threats arise from the policies of the largest countries, in particular when polices pursued in self-interest conflict with the collective interest. But, by definition, it is difficult for the rest of the world to change the incentives of the large country to give more weight to the collective interest. Successful cooperation is fated to falter if not fail—and the efforts of the IMF in this matter have often resulted in failure. As Mussa (2007) makes clear, “In none of these consultations has the Executive Board ever concluded that a member was out of compliance with its obligations regarding its exchange rate policies or any other matter” (emphasis in the original).19
Williamson (2011, p. 1) notes that “it has been 80 years since John Maynard Keynes first proposed a plan that would have disciplined persistent surplus countries. But the Keynes Plan, like the subsequent Volcker Plan in 1972–74, was defeated by the major surplus country of the day (the United States and Germany, respectively), and today China (not to mention Japan or Germany) exhibits no enthusiasm for new revisions of these ideas.” The question is whether there is anything that the rest of the world could have done—by way of sticks or carrots—to have persuaded the United States in 1944, Germany in 1973, or China in 2007 to change its positions or policies for the collective good.
19 Keynes himself recognized the asymmetry of IMF leverage between creditor and debtor countries in the discussion in the lead-up to the creation of the IMF.
The IMF’s ineffectiveness is a proximate manifestation of deeper structural causes related to leverage and legitimacy. Although the IMF has been able to effect changes in member country policies in the context of financial arrangements, it has not been influential without the leverage of financing. In its key surveillance function (which involves no financing), the IMF has rarely led to changes in the policies of large creditor countries, even when such policies have had significant spillover effects on countries; it has not been able to persuade large creditor countries to sacrifice domestic objectives for systemic ones. There seems to be an implicit “pact of mutual nonaggression,” to use Mussa’s phrase, in IMF surveillance. Perhaps as a result, the IMF has had a history and tradition of nonadversarial dialogue between its members and has not had to develop a real dispute settlement system.20
Compounding this problem of limited leverage is the IMF’s eroding legitimacy. Although its role and importance were rehabilitated with the recent global financial crisis, the perception of the IMF as an unreliable interlocutor in emerging market countries—Asia in particular—endures. A good example is the IMF’s new conditionality-lite financing facility, which has few takers because some emerging market countries do not want to be seen as even potential borrowers from the IMF. Indeed, in 2009, a number of emerging market countries—Brazil, Singapore, and the Republic of Korea—preferred to get lines of credit from the U.S. Federal Reserve than the IMF.
The WTO seems to be different on these two counts of legitimacy and leverage, because it works on the basis of the exchange of concessions, which ensures that all players feel that they have derived a fair political “bargain.” Reciprocity ensures political buy-in to cooperation. Periodic negotiations in the GATT/WTO have updated this political contract between countries, redressing some old grievances and papering over others, with the implicit understanding that there will be a future occasion to take up the unsolvable problems of the day.
20 A corollary of the observation that cooperation is least likely where the self-interest of the largest countries are at stake is that the prospects for successful cooperation are greater where these countries are less affected and when the demands on them are minimal. Building global safety nets by providing greater and more expeditious access to crisis financing is one area where the greatest progress has already been made. The IMF’s lending ability tripled after the crisis, and it may increase further. For the large countries, it is both desirable and effective to push for larger safety nets. The costs are relatively small— involving larger financial contributions rather than any major change of domestic policies—and the rewards are great, because the system as a whole is strengthened while the individual clout of the large countries is increased (see Goldstein 2009).
A consequence of reciprocity and the periodic updating of the political contract to cooperate— and another reason why the WTO works—is that this process creates incentives to adhere to the dispute settlement contract. Dispute settlement by the WTO is effective largely because countries feel that they have previously (and recently) made a reasonably advantageous, fair, and equitable bargain, to which they must adhere. WTO governance works because negotiations to create the rules and agree on liberalization are perceived as fair and broadly equitable in outcome, rendering subsequent compliance possible.21
Trade, Climate Change, and Green Growth
Do the institutions and ideology of globalization come in the way of tackling climate change? In one very important respect, they may.22
Consider two episodes from 2012. In late 2012, the United States and the European Union sanctioned the use of antidumping duties against Chinese exports of solar panels on the grounds that Chinese manufacturers were “dumping” (selling below cost) solar panels manufactured in China. In the presidential debates, President Obama was on the defensive against Mitt Romney, who tried (with some success) to tar him with the “failed industrial policy” brush in relation to government support for clean energy and Solyndra, a producer of solar panels that filed for bankruptcy two years after receiving substantial government loans and guarantees. These examples illustrate how international rules and ideology (which underlie rules) could come in the way of efforts to tackle climate change.
Mattoo and Subramanian (2012b) argue that only radical technological change can reconcile climate change goals with the development and energy aspirations of the bulk of humanity. Technological change requires the deployment of the full range of policy instruments that would raise the price of carbon and provide incentives for research and development of noncarbon-intensive sources of energy and related green technologies. With notable exceptions, countries have shown great reluctance to raise the price of carbon directly.
21 Experience suggests that the mere prospect of retaliation, as well as the reluctance to be seen as a rule breaker, is sufficient to ensure compliance and that there is rarely need for action.
22 This section is based on Mattoo and Subramanian (2013).
International rules severely restrict the use of subsidies. Under current WTO rules, domestic subsidies for the development and production of clean energy and related energy technologies are actionable by partner countries if those countries feel that their domestic production or exports are adversely affected. Until 2000, some of these subsidies were deemed nonactionable, but the exemption has not been renewed. Moreover, all forms of export subsidy involving clean energy and/or green technologies are prohibited. These rules are in place because of the ideology that imbues globalization—the notion that subsidies and all forms of industrial policy are dubious.
In relation to climate change, these rules are doubly bad. There is, of course, a logic to curtailing subsidies: even if they confer domestic benefits, those benefits are outweighed by the damage to partner countries. A multilateral rule to which there is general adherence reduces that damage, potentially leaving countries better off. But in the case of climate change, because spillovers are global, any subsidy that promotes clean energy and development confers a benefit to partner countries. On balance, therefore, rules should err on the side of promoting rather than restricting subsidies.
There is a second, arguably bigger, political economy benefit. Prospects for climate change action in the United States in the form of a carbon tax or cap-and-trade are not bright. President Obama’s grand rhetoric in his 2013 State of the Union speech is unlikely to be matched by bold action because of the lack of bipartisan support in Congress. This state of affairs reflects a combination of factors—climate change denial, the strength of the carbon energy industries, and weak economic prospects. There is probably only one development that could galvanize action in the United States: the threat that China will capture green technology leadership. The United States needs a Sputnik moment of collective alarm at the loss of economic and technological ascendancy.
The problem is that China is currently constrained by WTO rules, as the actions against its firms in 2012 illustrate.23 China and all countries that are not straitjacketed by the tyranny of the susbsidies-are-bad ideology and that have the financial means to do so should be allowed to deploy industrial policy to promote clean energy and green technologies. If doing so leads to a subsidy war because partners feel threatened, that is a war that should be promoted, as it will ignite the race for the development and production of an undersupplied global public good. From this perspective, WTO rules should allow not only domestic but also export subsidies; current rules circumscribe the use of domestic and prohibit the use of export subsidies.24
Trade and Scarcity of Food and Resources
The 2007 global food crisis was severe.25 According to the World Bank, about 100 million people are estimated to have been thrown back into the ranks of the poor because of increases in the price of food. Riots occurred in a number of countries. The Bank identified 33 countries as especially vulnerable. The poor were especially vulnerable because they spend the largest portions of their income on food. In the United States, the poor spend an estimated 18 percent of their income on food; a similar measure for households earning less than $1 a day is about 72 percent in Peru and South Africa, 66 percent in Indonesia, and 50 percent in Mexico (Banerjee and Duflo 2011).
23 In fact, China stopped providing subsidies to its solar power companies in response to trade action by the United States. “The U.S. Trade Representative’s Office responded by filing a complaint in December with the WTO saying China violated rules of the Geneva-based trade arbiter. China’s Special Fund for Wind Power Manufacturing required recipients of aid to use Chinese- made parts and amounted to a prohibited subsidy, the U.S. said. Before the WTO acted on the complaint, China made it moot by ending that aid in June, according to the U.S.” (http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2011-09-23/blame-china-chorus-grows-as-solyndra-fails-amid-cheap-imports.html).
24 Another area in which trade restrictions should be permitted are border tariffs against imports from countries that do not tax carbon in the manner that the importing country does. Such tariffs would help overcome opposition from energy-intensive industries in countries wishing to raise the price of carbon on the grounds that they would be rendered uncompetitive relative to imports from countries that do not tax carbon. A final area in which WTO rules need to be clarified is export restrictions on natural gas, which is becoming an important fuel. The U.S. currently limits its exports to countries with which it does not have a free trade agreement. If greater global use of natural gas is desirable (because it is cleaner than substitutes such as oil and coal), then restrictions on exports may be deleterious for global energy emissions.
25 This section draws on Mattoo and Subramanian (2012a).
But pressure on food supplies, and associated high food prices, could be a medium- to long-term reality, because some of the driving factors—rising prosperity in the developing world, which creates more demand; high fuel prices; stagnant agricultural productivity; and climate change– induced pressure on agricultural supplies, including through the depletion of water—could be of a durable nature. These fundamentals are being exacerbated by export restrictions on foodstuffs. According to a World Bank report, in the 2007 crisis, 18 developing countries imposed some form of export restrictions (Zaman and others 2008). Each country was trying to keep domestic supplies high, on the grounds of food security. But as more countries implemented export controls, global supply contracted, pushing prices up and exacerbating global food insecurity. The global rice market was particularly affected by trade restrictions.26
There are few restrictions on the use of export taxes in the WTO, and its disciplines on export restrictions are incomplete. The GATT does prohibit quantitative restrictions on exports, but temporary restrictions are permitted in order to prevent critical shortages of food or other goods.
This permissiveness on export taxes and restrictions is resulting in the worst of all possible worlds. Under “normal” agricultural conditions, costly taxpayer support reduces imports and encourages production and exports, creating huge distortions. Under abnormal conditions, such as are prevailing now, the opposite occurs: countries liberalize their imports but prevent exports. What is needed is a system in which both imports and exports remain free to flow in good times and bad. Such a system is especially important if trade is to remain a reliable avenue for food security. If in bad times importing countries are subject to the export-restricting actions of producing countries, they will consider trade an unreliable way of maintaining food security and reconsider how to manage their agriculture. As a result, there will be a greater temptation to move toward more self-reliance as insurance against the bad times.27
26 Food security goals are best served not by restricting trade but by deploying domestic policy instruments such as targeted safety nets. The existence of such safety nets would dilute the political economy bias in favor of trade interventions.
27 Not surprisingly, WTO members that depend heavily on world markets for food (for example, Japan and Switzerland in 2000; the Democratic Republic of Congo, Jordan, and the Republic of Korea in 2001) have pushed for disciplines on export controls and taxes. Recognizing that importers’ concerns about the reliability of supply could inhibit liberalization, some exporting countries have advocated for multilateral restrictions on the right to use export restrictions (examples include the Cairns Group and the United States in 2000 and Japan and Switzerland in 2008) (International Economic Law and Policy Blog 2008).
The Doha Round of trade negotiations did not address these problems. It was devoted to traditional forms of agricultural protection—trade barriers in the importing countries and subsidies to food production in producing countries—which are now becoming less important as food prices have soared and import barriers declined. The trade agenda needs to be enlarged, so that trade barriers, on both imports and exports, are put on the trade agenda.
Trade policies have also exacerbated the scarcity of nonfood resources. Concerns have already arisen over China’s restriction of exports of rare earth metals, for some of which (for example, scandium and yttrium) it accounts for more than 70 percent of the world’s exports. It also accounts for a large shares of exports of other key raw materials, including various forms of bauxite, magnesium, and zinc.28
4. Fundamental Policy Challenges
The period of hyperglobalization has been associated with the most dramatic turnaround in the economic fortunes of developing countries. Regardless of the view one takes about this association, it is safe to say that a broadly open system is good for the world, good for individual countries, and good for average citizens in these countries. Going forward, even if the pace of hyperglobalization slows, the aim of policy at the national and collective level must be to sustain steady and rising globalization and avoid sharp reversals.
The previous section illustrated some of the proximate challenges. They can be addressed only if the deeper challenges are recognized and addressed.
One way of approaching these more fundamental policy challenges is suggested in table 4.1, which helps identify the problems and hence to prioritize the policy response. This schematic can be applied to three broad groups of countries (high, middle, and low income), the challenges and responses for each of which may differ.
28 In an earlier case, a WTO panel ruled against certain export restrictions China had maintained on a number of raw materials, including bauxite, coke, fluorspar, magnesium, and zinc.
Table 4.1 Policy Responses to the Challenges to Globalization
Level of response | Further liberalize | Maintain status quo | Retreat from globalization |
---|---|---|---|
National | – In low-income countries, strengthen domestic supply capacity to exploit globalization. – In China and other middle-income countries, sustain growth to enable further liberalization. – In high-income countries, revive growth and address “beleaguered middle class” and entitlements problems | Strengthen social insurance in high-income countries. | |
International/collective | – Prevent fragmentation and conflict. – Sustain multilateralism through a “China Round.” | Cooperate on taxation of mobile factors to sustain domestic safety net. | Create minimum safeguards to allow some trade protection? |
What are the really important challenges for the open trading system, and how should they be responded to? If the next couple of decades mimic or come close to mimicking the last two in terms of globalization, success will have been unambiguous. The challenge is thus simply to maintain the status quo and allow the forces that have shaped globalization over the last few decades to play themselves out.
Alternatively, one could argue that globalization needs to advance on a number of different dimensions—because, for example, impediments remain to the prospects of average citizens, especially in low-income countries. The need for further globalization could also stem from the perception that in some respects, the current system is unsustainable, because it is differentially open and the burden of providing open markets is not equally shared, especially by China.
A third logical possibility is that the forces that will push against globalization are, or will become, so strong that a retreat from current globalization is inevitable. The challenge then will be to manage this retreat in a way that minimizes the costs to countries and citizens around the world.
The responses to each of these challenges can occur at the national level, at the international level, or through some combination of national and collective action. The responses to these challenges are discussed below.
The West’s Challenge: Hyperglobalization Meets Economic Decline
The bad news
Public support for free trade agreements in the United States is at its lowest point since 2006, according to the Pew Center (2010)—and the decline occurred quickly. In 2009, the share of people who supported free trade agreements exceeded the share who opposed it by a margin of 11 percentage points. In 2010, opponents of free trade outnumbered supporters by 8 percentage points. Surprisingly, among Republican-leaning voters, the turnaround was even more dramatic: the margin in 2009 was 7 percentage points in favor of free trade agreements; the margin in 2010 was 26 percentage points against free trade agreements. This weakening collective perception of the benefits of openness is matched, mirrored, or validated by intellectual opinion.
Samuelson (2004) argues that the rise of developing countries such as China and India could compromise living standards in the United States, because as they move up the technology ladder, they provide competition for U.S. exports, reducing their price. Krugman (2008) focuses on the impact of imports from developing countries, particularly China, on the distribution of income in the United States and the wages of less-skilled workers. His conclusion is that “it is likely that the rapid growth of trade since the early 1990s has had significant distributional effects” and that “it is probably true that this increase (in manufactured imports from developing countries)… has been a force for greater inequality in the United States and other developed countries” (Krugman 2008, 134–35).
Blinder (2009) draws attention to the employment and wage consequences of the outsourcing that has been facilitated by technological change and trade in services. He estimates that 22–29 percent of all U.S. jobs will be offshored or offshorable within the next decade or two.
Summers (2008a, 2008b) has highlighted the problems stemming from increasing capital mobility. Hypermobile U.S. capital creates a double whammy for American workers. First, as companies flee in search of cheaper labor abroad, American workers become less productive (because they have less capital to work with) and hence receive lower wages; the “exit” option for capital also reduces the incentive to invest in domestic labor. Second, capital mobility impairs the ability of domestic policy to respond to labor’s problem through redistribution because of an erosion in the tax base as countries compete to attract capital by reducing their tax rates.
Spence and Hlatshwayo (2011) argue that almost all the increase in employment of 27.3 million jobs in the United States between 1990 and 2008 was in the nontradable sectors, where productivity growth was much slower than in the manufacturing and tradable sectors, explaining the long-term stagnation of wages in the last segment of the workforce.
That a constellation of intellectuals—instinctively cosmopolitan and ideologically liberal—talks like this is an important signal, not least because the objective circumstances have changed. One might call this challenge that of the irresistible force of globalization and hyperglobalization meeting the immovable object of weakening economic and fiscal fortunes in the West.
In the United States, except for a brief spell in the late 1990s, median wages have stagnated for three decades; inequality has been sharply rising, particularly because of rising incomes at the very top of the income spectrum (Piketty and Saez 2003); and mobility has declined (Haskins, Isaac, and Sawhill 2008) Worse, as in all industrial countries, indebtedness has risen (average debt in the G-7 is now about 80 percent of GDP), prospects for medium-term growth in the future are not bright (according to the latest World Economic Outlook forecast), and aging and entitlements add to the serious fiscal pressures looming ahead. These objective conditions are not the most propitious for sustaining globalization.
This structural malaise is captured in the following metaphor that Larry Katz, of Harvard, uses: “Think of the American economy as a large apartment block. A century ago—even 30 years ago—it was the object of envy. But in the last generation its character changed. The penthouses at the top keep getting larger and larger. The apartments in the middle are feeling more and more squeezed, and the basement has flooded. To round it off, the elevator is no longer working. That broken elevator is what gets people down the most” (quoted by Luce 2010).
The policy challenge in the advanced countries is that sustaining current levels of openness will require addressing these domestic challenges at the very time when growth could be slowing and the ability to effect redistribution is being impeded by broader medium-term fiscal concerns. In this light, the changing attitudes to globalization and free trade cited above are not surprising.
We focus here on what is now different in the West’s ability to sustain globalization. A starting point is the view, described in Rodrik (1998), that sustaining openness requires a domestic social consensus in its favor, which in turn requires mechanisms of social insurance to cushion domestic actors against globalization-induced shocks. Rodrik (1998) provides evidence showing that this domestic consensus can be captured in the relationship between the size of government (a proxy for social insurance mechanisms) and openness.
More direct evidence of the importance of social insurance comes from a paper by Autor, Dorn, and Hanson (2013), who show that rising exposure to Chinese imports increases unemployment, lowers labor force participation, and reduces wages in local labor markets. They estimate that the exogenous component of this shock explains one-quarter of the contemporaneous aggregate decline in U.S. manufacturing employment. They estimate that rising exposure to Chinese import competition explains about 16 percent of the decline in U.S. manufacturing employment between 1991 and 2000 and 27 percent of the decline between 2000 and 2007. Transfer payments for unemployment, disability, retirement, and health care also rise sharply in exposed labor markets. They estimate the increase in annual per capita transfers attributable to rising Chinese import competition at $32 in the first 10 years and $51 in the last 7 years of the sample, which translates into total expenditure of about $5 billion in the 1990s and almost $15 billion in the 2000s. The deadweight loss of financing these transfers is one-third to two-thirds as large as U.S. gains from trade with China.
Can the West sustain these social insurance mechanisms? According to Summers (2008a), globalization both increases the need for social insurance and undermines the government’s ability to provide it, because it renders more factors, especially capital and high-skilled labor, more mobile and less easy to tax.
Has capital become less easy to tax? Figure 4.1 plots the marginal effective tax rates on capital in some important OECD countries and for the OECD as a whole. These rates have been sharply declining, and there is little pressure to reverse these trends.
Figure 4.1 Tax Rates on Distributed Corporate Profits in Selected OECD Countries, 1981–2012
For the OECD as a whole, the average marginal tax rate declined from about 55 percent to almost 40 percent, a 15 percentage point decline. These declines were witnessed across most if not all countries. In the United States, rates declined from 65 percent to just over 50 percent; in Germany they fell from about 60 percent to less than 50 percent. Of course, these declines reflect pressures other than globalization and the attendant difficulty of heavily taxing mobile capital, but these pressures have been important.
A new development adds to the problems. Across the OECD, the share of the economic pie accruing to capital has been increasing, increasing from about 35 percent to 40 percent in the last few years (figure 4.2). This increasing share has prompted several commentators, including Krugman, to argue that the debate about inequality and trade and inequality in the 1990s, which related to inequality within types of labor (skilled versus unskilled), should now be viewed through a different lens, because inequality is increasingly between capital (and those who own it) and labor.
Figure 4.2 Share of Capital in National Income in Selected OECD Countries, 1980–2012
For the purposes of our argument, what is important is this: Not only is the ability to finance mechanisms of social insurance being undermined by weak growth and the burden of debt (Ruggie 1998); slippery, mobile capital is now accounting for a larger share of the economic pie. The funding of social insurance through taxation is thus going to become more difficult.
The good news: The protectionist dog that barked but did not bite
Several commentators have remarked on the fact that despite suffering perhaps the biggest global trade shock in the recent global financial crisis, the world did not succumb to protectionism. This response stood in stark contrast to the experience of the 1930s. Explanations for the difference have included the facts that (a) countries could use macroeconomic policy instruments (monetary and exchange rate), which adherence to the gold standard initially prevented in the 1930s (Eichengreen and Irwin 2009); (b) automatic stabilizers were in place, by way of transfers and unemployment benefits (Autor, Dorn, and Hanson 2013); and (c) the deeper integration created by modern production chains rendered protectionism self-defeating (Baldwin and Evenett 2009).
The bigger puzzle is this: How did the West, and the United States in particular, adjust to arguably the biggest structural trade shock in its history—namely, rising imports from China—without any serious recourse to protectionism? Why was there less protectionist outrage in the United States against China than there was against Mexico in the 1990s or Japan in the 1980s? The domestic uproar against China did not match the backlash created in the context of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), and actual protectionist actions did not come remotely close to the actions taken against Japan (the Reagan era witnessed the greatest upsurge in trade barriers in the postwar period; see Destler 1992).
The differences cannot be explained by the relative magnitude of the three shocks, as the Chinese shock was orders of magnitude larger than the early shocks. Figure 4.3 plots imports from Mexico, Japan, and China as a share of U.S. domestic consumption between 1962 and 2011. At their peaks, Japan accounted for 3.6 percent of U.S. consumption, whereas China accounts for about 5.2 percent.29
Figure 4.3 Import Shocks in the United States from Mexico, Japan, and China, 1962–2011
Table 4.2 quantifies the trade shocks to the United States from the three countries. The shock is computed in three ways (each scaled by the working-age population in the United States or the domestic consumption of manufacturing): (a) average imports over the relevant period (for convenience, all shocks are considered to extend over a 20-year period: Japan 1970–90, Mexico 1980–2000, and China 1990–2010); (b) the change in imports over the period30; and (c) both average changes and changes calibrated by per capita GDP in each country.
29 Appendix figure A.3 plots the same data but for a shorter period for which value-added trade data can be computed. Gross exports overstate value-added exports for China, but they overstate them even more for Mexico.
30 Trefler (1993) shows that cross-industry differences in protection are associated with the change in import penetration, not its absolute value. Autor, Dorn, and Hanson (2013) use import penetration as a share of working-age population as the measure of trade shock.
Table 4.2 Magnitude of Import Shocks to the United States from Japan, Mexico, and China
As table 4.2 shows, depending on the measure used, the Chinese shock was either 4–5 or 10 times as great as the Japanese and Mexican shocks. Calibrated by per capita GDP, it was even greater. (One reason to calibrate by per capita GDP is that trade with low-income countries is of the Hecksher-Ohlin variety. It therefore imposes greater domestic political costs [than, say, trade in similar goods between countries at similar levels of development], in particular because these costs are disproportionately borne by unskilled labor, which competes more directly with foreign imports.31)
Several explanations are possible for the differential response to the China shock. One could be that the measure of recorded imports exaggerates the trade shock because of the difference between gross flows and value-added flows. Chinese exports embody less value added than the exports of many other countries because of the large volume of intermediate inputs it imports and transforms into exports. Even making allowances for this distinction, however—and the problem was arguably as acute in relation to Mexican maquiladora exports to the United States—would hardly make a dent in the numbers presented above. 32
31 Krugman (1995) elaborated on the reasons for intra-industry trade posing fewer political problems compared with Hecksher-Ohlin trade.
32 In appendix table A.1, the figures for China are recomputed based on value-added trade data (we cannot do the same for the Mexican and Japanese shocks, which would bias the comparison in favor of understating the China shock). The size of the Chinese shock declines, but it remains orders of magnitude larger than the earlier shocks from Japan and Mexico.
A second explanation could be that in the case of Mexico, the uproar was exaggerated because there was a focal point: a trade agreement that had to be passed by the U.S. Congress. But in the case of China, there has also been an identifiable target and identifiable policies: currency manipulation. Moreover, Mexico was an ally, whereas China is a potential adversary and competitor to big power status, which should have increased the outcry and concerns in domestic U.S. politics.
A third explanation is that by the time the China trade shock arrived, the United States had specialized so much away from unskilled labor that there was less to disturb domestically. For example, the number of workers employed in the U.S. clothing sector declined from 900,000 in 1990 to 150,000 in 2013. In technical terms, the United States is no longer in the cone of diversification (Edwards and Lawrence 2013). The estimates of employment disruption by Autor, Dorn, and Hanson (2013) for the Chinese case suggest that this argument cannot be a full, or even an important, explanation, however.
A fourth argument for the relatively muted domestic response is that the size of the Chinese market and the strategy of openness to U.S. FDI essentially coopted U.S. companies and capital, which had an incentive to support rather than criticize China. The Japanese experience was different from the Chinese experience in two important respects: trade conflict with Japan reflected head-to-head competition in some specific industries (steel, cars, semiconductors) rather than conflict based on unequal endowments. It was U.S. capital rather than labor that was the victim in the Japan episode; as it had unusual influence in the political process, there was correspondingly more of a response. In addition, Japan had not created the same stake for U.S. companies in Japan as China had.
Finally, it is possible that the underlying macroeconomic situation was better when the Chinese export juggernaut arrived.
One conclusion from all this is that if U.S. domestic politics could survive a shock as great as that from China, there may be an underlying resilience (helped considerably by government insurance mechanisms) that should not be underestimated. Moreover, it could be argued that structural shocks similar to China’s are unlikely to repeat themselves. This fact should temper unremitting pessimism about the future of globalization.
One can generalize the Chinese experience in the United States more broadly to other advanced countries. Figures 4.4 and 4.5 illustrate the change in OECD country imports in favor of developing countries. They plot the average income level of manufactured imports into the United States, Japan, and the Europe Union. The per capita GDP level of each source country, measured relative to that of the importing country, is weighted by its share in total manufactured imports of the reporting country (in figure 4.4, the per capita GDP and import share are contemporaneous; in figure 4.5, the per capita GDP is fixed at the 1980 level). In all cases, imports from the early 1990s are being sourced progressively from poorer countries, suggesting an increase in competition from lower-wage countries. In the European Union, for example, the average income level of imports drops from 100 percent to 75 percent. The point is that all advanced economies have experienced large trade shocks, without recourse to serious protectionism.33
33 The value-added counterpart of figures 4.4 and 4.5 are appendix figures A.2 and A.3. The broad trends remain the same.
Figure 4.4 Relative Income Level of Exporters to the European Union, Japan, and United States, 1980–2010
Note: The measure represented here is the weighted average income level of exporters to the European Union, Japan, the United States, excluding oil exporters (as defined by the IMF) and small countries (countries with populations of less than 1 million). Income level is per capita GDP (purchasing power parity) using the rgdpch measure in the Penn World Tables. For example, if we call this index RIEU,t for the European Union, it is computed as
where Mi,EU is imports by the European Union from i and M is total imports by the European Union. RIJP,t and RIUS,t are identically computed for Japan and the United States.
Figure 4.5 Relative Income Level of Exporters to the European Union, Japan, and the United States with Fixed Weights, 1980–2010
Note: See note to figure 4.4. GDP weights are fixed to their initial 1980 value. The fixed-weight index
becomes:
The China Challenge: Bretton Woods Rules or Hyperglobalization Rules?
China will play a critical role in shaping the future of globalization, just as the United States did in the immediate aftermath of World War II. Its economy is as large as the United States’ (in purchasing power parity terms) is as large, and its merchandise trade is larger. Over time, unless China implodes, the differential in economic strength will widen in its favor. Under reasonable assumptions about growth, China will become the dominant economic trader, accounting for twice as much trade as the United States and four times as much as Germany in 2030.
The China challenge will be twofold. As it becomes the world’s largest economy and trader, its markets will become more important for other countries, especially low-income ones. China will thus matter to globalization not just as an exporter but also as an importer.
This tension has been best exemplified in recent years by China’s mercantilist growth strategy. In this millennium, China’s growth and exports have been underpinned by an undervalued exchange rate, a policy that has been successful for China from a domestic perspective. By increasing the global export supply and depressing the global price of tradables, this policy may have set back the diversification possibilities of other poorer countries, however (Mattoo, Mishra, and Subramanian 2012).34
The China challenge is more broadly applicable to middle-income countries. On the one hand, these countries will continue to rely on trade and foreign markets as a means of increasing their growth. On the other hand, these countries and their markets are becoming big enough (as the projection for China suggested) to offer opportunities for the average citizen in other and poorer parts of the world. If China’s actions are market opening, there will be little conflict between its domestic imperatives and the demands of an open system. If, however, it uses its policy space to implement beggar-thy-neighbor policies, conflict with other countries, including poorer ones, will ensue.
A second, possibly more important challenge from China’s rise will pertain to the openness of the global system. After World War II, the United States initially bequeathed an open, rules-based trading system. Subsequently, reasonably successful cooperation between the two dominant trading powers—the United States and Europe—was achieved in the GATT/WTO through reciprocal exchange of market-opening commitments. Can this same mechanism be effective going forward with China as a dominant trader? Will it be possible to get China to reduce its policy barriers, especially in areas not covered by WTO rules, such as government procurement, investment rules, technology indigenization, and services sector policies?
34 Undervalued currencies are in effect both an import tax and an export subsidy; countries that maintain them wind up reducing the profitability of industries in countries with which they trade.
There may indeed be a structural problem limiting the scope for reciprocity. When the United States and European Union dealt with each other in the postwar period, their markets were largely open; in areas where they were closed, they were broadly closed to the same extent. This symmetry facilitated reciprocity. In the future, problems could arise because the United States and European Union are, in policy terms, more open than China.
China is highly open in terms of trade outcomes, and it has made great strides in removing policy barriers as part of WTO accession. It is, however, more closed in policy terms, especially outside the traditional goods area. In services, technology, and government procurement, closed policies take the form of continuing state control over a large share of economic activity. According to Borchert and others (2012), China’s services sector policies are about three times as restrictive as those of the United States. In the retail sector, for example, China limits foreign ownership to 49 percent if the retailer has set up 30 or more stores that sell multiple types and brands of goods. In any future bargain, the United States will, by virtue of previous liberalization, have less to offer China.
The paradox will be that China will have greater leverage in bargaining by virtue of its much larger volume of trade but will also have higher trade policy barriers. It is as if in a duel, one party offers a smaller target and has a pistol with longer range. By 2020, China’s imports will be 1.5 larger than the United States’ and twice as large as Germany’s, conferring the kind of power that comes with being able to determine access to its markets. Future bargaining will therefore be structurally imbalanced in China’s favor, making reciprocity more difficult to achieve.
This structural imbalance will be a persistent source of tension between the United States and China. As U.S. manufacturing sector hollows out, and the United States comes to rely to an even greater degree on services, it will seek to open markets overseas, especially in China. If China’s future opening is slow, over time the United States may be increasingly tempted to play the unfairness card based on the disparate levels of policy openness: Why should our markets be more open than those of a rival and equal?
This imbalance in bargaining could remain at the level of sparring and skirmishing without systemic consequences. But suppose failures to address its structural economic problems—stagnating median household income, rising inequality, declining economic mobility—creates a large, disaffected, and beleaguered middle class in the United States and that the intellectual consensus in favor of openness becomes increasingly frayed, as it has in the last few years. Frustrated by China’s unwillingness to open the new sectors of its economy and lacking the carrots to overcome its unwillingness, spurred by a weak economic climate and shifting intellectual certitudes, and goaded by perceptions that China is not making its fair contribution to keeping markets open, the United States could be tempted to threaten to close its own market to China unless China further opens its own. In this scenario, especially if China cannot wean itself off mercantilism and state capitalism, the scope for trade conflict and tension could increase considerably, jeopardizing the openness of the global system.
Concerns about China’s trade policies have not been confined to rich countries. The Chinese export juggernaut is a source of concern across the developing world. Brazil, India, Mexico, Korea, South Africa, and other emerging market countries chafe under China’s mercantilist exchange rate policies. Most of the antidumping actions taken by developing countries have been against Chinese imports. And one of the dirty secrets of the Doha Round is that its collapse was caused in part by the reluctance of emerging market countries to liberalize their economies and expose themselves to Chinese competition.35
35 In 2009, China’s share of imports in the most protected sectors was substantially larger than its share of overall imports and dwarfed that of any other supplier. Its share in these sectors was more than 70 percent in Japan; more than 60 percent in Korea; about 55 percent in Brazil; and about 50 percent each in the United States, Canada, and the European Union. Even in these protected sectors, China’s share increased dramatically over the course of the Doha Round. In many importing countries (for example, Brazil, the European Union, and the United States), China’s share more than doubled. Also striking is how much market share China has gained even in countries such as Canada, Mexico, and Turkey, which have free trade agreements with close and large neighbors. Thus, liberalization under the Doha agenda, especially in the politically charged, high-tariff sectors, is increasingly about other countries opening their markets to Chinese exports (Mattoo and Subramanian 2012a).
So a big, first-order question for the open system is how to prompt China to adopt more open policies. The problem becomes acute if one recognizes China’s economic dominance and the degree to which other countries have lost leverage to influence Chinese policies. A little over a decade ago, the West could essentially determine the terms of China’s accession to the WTO; that is no longer the case today.
The Changing Global Governance of Trade: Mega-regionalism Meets China
For a variety of reasons, regional integration has been, along with unilateral liberalization, the preferred mode of liberalization. As a result, the governance of world trade has shifted decisively toward regionalism and away from multilateralism.
So far, preferential trade agreements (PTAs) have been North-South “deep” regional trade agreements, occasioned in part by the rise of supply chains. A Doha Round that was midwifed in an unusual bout of post–9/11 world solidarity and saddled with an agenda of issues like agriculture and tariffs that have less relevance now than new issues (exchange rate mercantilism, services, government procurement, investment, export restrictions) also contributed to a preference for regionalism (Mattoo and Subramanian 2012a; Baldwin 2011b).
North-South PTAs have not posed a serious threat for globalization; in fact, they may have contributed to significant opening through a process of competitive liberalization. But this relatively benign outcome cannot be taken for granted in the case of the mega-regionals looming on the horizon. On the one hand, they will involve deep integration and facilitate further globalization. After all, the world trading system is already multilayered in terms of levels of integration (the European Union, the European Free Trade Agreement, customs unions, other free trade agreements, and so forth). A Trans-Pacific Partnership and Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership will just add another layer of integration.
On the other hand, such agreements could be exclusionary, depending on the extent to which they conform to the principles of open regionalism. Their effect will depend, above all, on how outsiders—the middle-income countries, especially China—react. If China views these agreements as economic war and containment by other means and retaliates by concluding its own regional agreements, excluding the large traders, fragmentation and conflict could lie ahead.
It is not that the WTO and multilateralism have become totally irrelevant. More and more countries, including Russia, want to join the WTO. Its dispute settlement system functions effectively, its basic rules are broadly respected. The question is whether it retains its relevance as a key forum for facilitating further liberalization or transforms itself into an institution that serves mainly as a court of trade law and an overseer of regional trade.
The (Non) Challenge of Low-Income Countries
The antiglobalization and anti–WTO crusade of the 1990s (culminating in the protests in Seattle in 1998) forced policy makers into a strenuous defense of the development friendliness of the trading system. The Doha Round, for example, was formally dubbed the Doha Development Agenda, which seems an overdone title.
The perception that the trading system is unfair to low-income countries stems from the fact that rich country trade barriers are highest in agriculture and low-skilled manufacturing (textiles, clothing, and footwear), which tend to be important exports for low-income countries. This situation changed over the last decade or so. Rich country barriers in these sectors declined in the aftermath of the Uruguay Round, with Canada, the European Union, the United States, and Japan all significantly improving preferential access to low-income countries, in terms of both country and product coverage (the European Union’s Everything But Arms and the United States’ Africa Growth and Opportunity Act are two notable examples). In some cases, these schemes also became less arbitrary.
As a consequence, low-income countries are at worst treated no worse than the typical country and at best treated better. Nearly all low-income countries (“least developed countries,” in the jargon of the trading system) face lower trade barriers than most other countries, because they receive generous preferences (albeit with some problems, depending on which country is granting them). There are some exceptions to these preferences (Bangladesh and Cambodia in clothing; West African countries facing rich country cotton subsidization). But even these exceptions create a situation only of parity with other countries. Increasingly, larger developing countries have also started granting preferential access to low-income countries, although the coverage and magnitude of this access are limited.
Hoekman and Nicita (2008) calculate that the average barriers facing exports of Sub-Saharan Africa are very low and much lower than for other countries. The average level of restrictiveness (including nontariff measures) that exports from Sub-Saharan Africa face in other markets—4.4 percent in high-income countries and 6.0 percent in upper-middle-income countries, taking account of preference margins—is consistently lower than for any group. The comparable numbers are 6.3 and 15.6 percent for high-income countries as exporters and 5.7 percent and 11.8 percent for upper-middle-income countries as exporters. (An exception is South Asia, which faces higher barriers because its exports face higher MFN tariffs and because countries such as India and Bangladesh are not included in the major preferential schemes, especially in the United States.)
Low-income countries also receive considerable space to pursue their own policies. In relation to rules on subsidies, intellectual property, and local content requirements, the least developed countries face weaker obligations. Moreover, the thresholds for taking contingent protectionist action (countervailing and antidumping) against exports of low-income countries are generally higher.
So it is not clear what more could be done for low-income countries internationally that would materially alter their growth prospects (box 4.1). Their growth challenges are predominantly domestic, as Dani Rodrik’s paper in this volume implies. Even recognizing the important point that Baldwin (2011a makes—that these countries need to get on to the new supply chains—it is not clear what other countries might do to galvanize this process, especially if the supply chain phenomenon is to some extent about geography.
Box 4.1 Helping Low-Income Countries in New Ways
Discussions of trade by low-income countries increasingly focus on supply chains. Summarizing a new report, Enabling Trade: Valuing Growth Opportunities, Hoekman (2013, p.13) suggests that “reducing supply chain barriers could increase global GDP up to six times more than removing all import tariffs. Estimates suggest that an ambitious improvement in two key components of supply chain barriers—border administration and transport and communications infrastructure—with all countries raising their performance halfway to global best practice (as observed in Singapore), would lead to an increase of approximately $2.6 trillion (4.7 percent) in global GDP and $1.6 trillion (14.5 percent) in global exports. By contrast, the gains available from complete worldwide tariff elimination amount to no more than $400 billion (0.7 percent) in global GDP and $1.1 trillion (10.1 percent) in global exports.”
The focus on supply chains, combined with the laudable aim of making the WTO more development friendly and helping low-income countries, has led concerned actors to push for “trade facilitation” and “aid-for-trade.” The argument for trade facilitation is that improving the procedures and institutions relating to trade and processing of trade would expand trade. Hoekman and Nicita (2011) claim that relatively limited actions to facilitate trade can boost the trade expansion effects by a factor of two, three or more.
Leaving aside these eye-popping quantitative estimates, the real issue relates to the changes in policies and practices in low-income countries that need to be changed. One often cited area is customs administration and procedures. The assumption underlying trade facilitation initiatives is that reforming customs is relatively easy. In fact, corruption is so rife that customs administration is fiendishly difficult to reform. A policy prescription that calls for customs reform is not very different from its behind-the-border counterpart that calls for improving institutions—something that is not easily done.
Moreover, trade facilitation assumes that governments should devote their policy effort to reforming customs administrations as opposed to reforming the judiciary or civil services more broadly. Advocates of trade facilitation never explain why trade should be prioritized.
The same assumptions pervade calls for “aid-for-trade.” The question of why not aid for health or education or other spheres is never addressed. Nor is the issue of whether aid can be effective in improving customs administration. Moreover, it turns out that reducing supply chain barriers is really about customs reform and reform of services sector policies within these countries, which are largely domestic agendas with a relatively limited role for outsiders.
As Borchert and others (2012) note, “Today, industrial countries provide ‘aid for trade’ to landlocked countries to improve their ports, airports, and telecommunications infrastructure. But they avoid the liberalisation that would let service providers compete to use these facilities. Their taxpayers and the development community need to push for services reform. Otherwise these ‘trade-facilitating’ investments will earn a poor return.”
For low-income countries, a trading system that allows them policy space to pursue appropriate growth strategies and that at the same time keeps global markets open for their exports is critical. After all, such was the external environment that allowed today’s middle-income countries to prosper. Despite the tightening of trade rules since the formation of the WTO, there remains enough policy space for these rules not to become a straitjacket for today’s low-income countries. Apart from some specific issues (such as food security), the real concern will be whether the external environment will remain as benign as in the previous two decades, so that low-income countries can export their way to growth. The actions of high- and middle-income countries will be critical.
5. Policy Responses
The key challenges facing globalization are sustaining domestic support for it in the West and ensuring that China continues to open its markets. Open markets in China are an important part of China’s domestic agenda for sustaining convergence. They also offer opportunities for poorer countries similar to those that China enjoyed in industrial countries over the last few decades. They are critical to keeping the trading system open and free of serious conflict. The challenge of mega-regionalism is related to the China challenge.
National Responses
Sustaining and furthering globalization will be determined at the national rather than the international level. For the United States and Europe, actions are needed to revive growth and address fiscal challenges, especially the challenges stemming from growing entitlements. For the United States, there is the additional challenge of addressing the problems of stagnating wages, rising inequality, and declining mobility. Success on these fronts will provide a surer guarantee that globalization will proceed apace. Several studies note that the demand for trade protection is inversely and robustly related to the state of the economy (see Rodrik 1998).
For its part, China should have a stake in preserving the open system for the simple reason that its rapid economic transformation over the last three decades was predicated crucially on openness. That transformation is still far from complete: China’s standard of living is still only 20–25 percent that of industrial countries. Completing that transformation is critical for the political legitimacy of China’s policy makers. In these circumstances, disrupting the open system would amount to biting the hand that has fed China and its rulers.
Indeed, going forward, the Chinese agenda for reforms, as elaborated in the government-imprimatured 2012 World Bank report China 2030, should be entirely consistent with an open system: China’s domestic needs are broadly outsiders’ wants. For example, the nontransparent practices of the state enterprises and the financial repression and closed nature of China’s capital account are a big concern for foreign firms trying to access the Chinese market and for firms around the world trying to compete with an undervalued Chinese currency. The more China reforms its state enterprises and state-owned banks, the easier it will be for foreigners to do business with China.
China 2030 calls on China to move more toward an innovation-based economy, which would require stronger protection of property rights, another key demand of outsiders. China needs to reduce its pollution and move toward a more carbon-efficient economy, which would allow it to play a constructive role in global climate change efforts. In all these cases, tensions will undoubtedly arise from differing senses of urgency about specific actions. But across the board, there is no fundamental conflict between what China needs to do domestically and what it needs to do to sustain an open system.
Of course, China could falter because its domestic problems—rising inequality and corruption, increased demands for accountability and participation, environmental deterioration—cannot be easily resolved. In this case, globalization would suffer.
International Responses to the Challenges Facing the West
International/collective responses can help in relation to both these challenges. In relation to the first, the increasing mobility of capital and its ability to escape taxation needs to be addressed. Rodrik (1997, p. 81) argues that this phenomenon “undercuts the revenue sources needed to maintain social and political cohesion and ultimately erodes support for free trade.” Two new developments have exacerbated this problem: capital has become more mobile (reflected in growing financial globalization and increased FDI flows), and the distribution of income in most OECD countries has moved substantially in favor of capital (and also in favor of high skilled people), increasing the size of the tax base that can elude taxation.
Figure 5.1 Share of Capital in National Income in Selected Country Groups, 1995–2008
In many emerging markets as well, especially China and India, capital is accounting for a larger share of the pie (figure 5.1). The global tax base (not just that of the OECD) is hence becoming more slippery. If countries and companies exploit the mobility of capital, the global ability to provide social insurance will decline, creating problems for globalization. Hence, there needs to be much greater cooperation between rich and emerging market countries (and, of course, tax havens) on how to tax capital and how to share the taxes from capital (Summers 2008b). This cooperation can take the form of greater harmonization (which would be difficult and entail a degree of regulatory convergence that countries will find difficult). Or it can take the form of countries doing their best to allow other countries to better enforce their own tax rules (a recent example involved Switzerland relaxing its secrecy laws to allow the United States to go after its tax evaders).
International Responses to the Challenge of China and Mega-Regionalism
The China challenge is a broader problem of cooperation in the face of a shift in economic power from the United States and Europe toward a rising one. It is in this context that even the new attempt at mega-regional agreements (Trans-Pacific Partnership and Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership) must be seen. At one level, these agreements are about deepening integration at a time when the multilateral liberalization process has become moribund and the Doha Round remains in cold storage. At another level, the issue is how the United States and European Union deal with the rise of China.36
At the risk of overgeneralizing, the challenge in the trade arena can be summarized as follows: China is happy with the status quo and the United States is not. China—and the other larger emerging markets, such as Brazil, India, and Russia—is reasonably content to have Bretton Woods rules apply to it and hyperglobalization rules apply to its large partners. China will liberalize and open up its markets in line with domestic rather than external imperatives. Its partners, especially the United States, will increasingly refuse to acquiesce in this status quo. But given China’s dominance and the weakness of the United States, the United States’ ability to force or induce China to change will be limited. The mega-regionalism demarche of the United States is an attempt to exert pressure on China.
How can these differing perspectives and positions be reconciled? The larger partners of the United States and China need to deploy a strategy that takes account of the possibility that China may occasionally be tempted into a less than-benign economic hegemony while reinforcing its incentives to act to preserve an open economic system.
36 In the case of the Trans-Pacific Partnership, containment is more political. With the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership, agreement by the United States and the European Union to common regulatory standards would preempt China from imposing its standards in international markets and even force China to adhere to these common standards.
The possibility of the misuse of hegemony would not be unique to China. It was famously said of the United Kingdom that Britannia ruled the waves by waiving the rules. The United States also occasionally succumbed to this temptation. In 1955, it excluded agriculture from GATT disciplines. In the early 1970s, it unilaterally blew up the Bretton Woods system when it became a straitjacket on domestic U.S. policies. In the 1980s and 1990s, it cajoled and coerced developing countries to take on costly obligations (relating to intellectual property and capital flows, for example). In the dark Nietschzean view that “power is never held in innocence,” misuse of hegemony is intrinsic to hegemony. It is inevitable given the infinite capacity for countries to succumb to the delusion that John Adams memorably warned about, that “power always thinks it has a great soul.”
History suggests that the best defense against hegemony is multilateralism, which offers a modicum of protection for the weak against the dominant power. Keeping China tethered to the multilateral system, in which the United States and other major countries can exercise some countervailing influence, offers the best insurance against its unrestrained exercise of hegemony.
Multilateralism could work as a defense against China in several ways: in shaping rules, in promoting adherence to them, and more broadly in defining legitimate behavior. With China’s growing size, the balance of negotiating power will be with China rather than its partners. Multilateralism ensures that China’s trading partners will have enough heft to negotiate with China in a more balanced manner. For example, China might be willing to open its markets in return for the United States, European Union, India, and Brazil opening theirs. Its willingness to open up in a similar manner in negotiations with just the United States or European Union or with some less powerful combination is far from clear.
A similar argument carries over to enforcement and the incentives to adhere to previously agreed upon rules. China’s incentive to abide by multilateral rules will be stronger than its incentive to abide by a series of bilateral agreements, because the reputational costs of being seen as errant are much greater in the multilateral context. The opprobrium of being a deviant from multilateral norms is China’s great fear, rendering multilateralism the best weapon the world can deploy against a dominant China.
These arguments for multilateralism have an important corollary for the United States and other countries. They imply less recourse to bilateral and regional dealings with China and with each other. The more countries elevate the role of bilateralism in dealings with China, the less China will be anchored in the multilateral system and the more exposed countries will be to the exercise of Chinese dominance. One operational consequence, advocated by Lieberthal and Wang (2012), is to expand the U.S.–China strategic economic dialogue to include the larger countries in the world—Europe, Japan, Brazil, and India, for a start—whose heft can be an effective counterweight to that of China.
These arguments in favor of multilateralism and against regionalism and bilateralism apply across the board in the fields of currency, finance, and trade. But they carry particularly important implications in the field of trade because of the current environment, in which the WTO appears moribund and regional initiatives are flourishing. The recent trade initiatives of the Obama administration—the Trans-Pacific and Trans-Atlantic partnerships—are regional initiatives. As box 5.1 suggests, they are particularly fraught in the context of a rising China.
Box 5.1 Multilateralism versus Regionalism: The Risks from the Trans-Pacific Partnership
In the old debate between regionalists and multilateralists, the divide was not about the end-point: all parties wanted global free trade. Rather, the divide was over whether regional agreements would be, in Jagdish Bhagwati’s words, a building block or a stumbling block in the way of that goal, with the regionalists falling in the former category and the multilateralists in the latter.
Regionalists would point to the evident success of regionalism in achieving deeper liberalization: in many or most cases, border barriers have been eliminated in goods and services, and in some, behind-the-border barriers have also been addressed. But both forms of regionalism involving China render this old debate less relevant.
No major country has yet embraced regional agreements with China (although the Association for Southeast Asian Nations [ASEAN] has embarked on this path). The arguments against regionalism are really the flip side of the arguments for multilateralism: negotiating with China will lead to agreements that are weighted in favor of China, because it has bargaining power. If the basic problem is the imbalance of leverage arising from China’s size, regionalism will by definition be less effective than multilateralism. For the same reason, getting China to adhere to these agreements will also be difficult.
But countries are increasingly negotiating agreements around China, with the Trans-Pacific Partnership representing the best recent example. Advocates of regionalism have long relied on the competitive dynamic it creates: if two countries negotiate preferential reductions of barriers, one or several outsiders will be hurt. These outsiders will then have an incentive to negotiate preferential agreements themselves. This process would will until the goal of global free trade is achieved—or so went the Bergsten-Zoellick theory of regionalism as promoting competitive liberalization.
But consider three ways in which the Trans-Pacific Partnership might play out. In the first, the United States embarks on a process of deep integration with a number of Asia Pacific countries without China. To avoid the dangers of hostile regionalism (that is, excluding China), Trans-Pacific Partnership countries could subscribe to the principle of open regionalism: countries get all of the agreement’s benefits only if they embrace its terms.
The problem with this approach is that China would never agree to fall in line with rules it did not participate in negotiating. For example, if Trans-Pacific Partnership members negotiated rules against undervalued exchange rates, China would probably stay away. If it did, the agreement would hardly achieve the objective of disciplining problematic Chinese policies that adversely affect the open character of the trading system.
In the second scenario, the United States invites China to the Trans-Pacific Partnership negotiating table to be part of the process of creating the rules. Would its participation really be superior to negotiating with China multilaterally, where the European Union, Brazil, and India would also be at the table? If the problem of a rising China is that it will have enormous bargaining power by virtue of its economic size and dominance, then a multilateral process will add more negotiating heft on the other side of the negotiation. How can it not help to have Brazil and India and Europe as part of the group putting pressure on China to create better rules and to adhere to them? Of course, there is no guarantee that Brazil and India will always be on the side applying pressure on China. But where important interests are at stake, they are likely to do so.
In the much worse third scenario, China construes the Trans-Pacific Partnership as an act of hostile regionalism (Yao Yang’s [2013] reaction is typical of this perception) and negotiates preferential agreements of its own—with, say, the European Union alone. Such a situation would create significant trade diversion for U.S. and other exporters because of high Chinese levels of protection in certain areas. The Trans-Pacific Partnership could thus provoke China into playing the regionalism game in a way that could fundamentally fragment the trading system. Down this path lies the folly of the interwar years.
In sum, the Trans-Pacific Partnership will either exclude China (and open regionalism may have little sway in persuading China to join) or be less effective in engaging China, because it would exclude other large trading countries (the European Union, Brazil, and India), whose collective heft might be crucial in balancing the bargaining power of China. The lesson is that the success of regionalism in reducing barriers and generating the competitive dynamic for further liberalization simply cannot be applied to China. The successes of regionalism typically involved a big economic power (the United States, the European Union, Japan) negotiating with smaller countries. The smaller countries did most of the incremental liberalization, because the larger countries held the balance of negotiating power and influence. With China, the power balance is reversed, rendering many of the old arguments for regionalism obsolete.
Regional and discriminatory solutions carry greater risks. The challenge of anchoring China in the multilateral trading system—as well as providing a fillip to growth in industrial countries through further liberalization—can be addressed by embarking on a new and comprehensive multilateral initiative. This initiative would anticipate the changing interests and concerns of all the big trading nations in a way that the Doha agenda did not. It would also pave the way for a reciprocal liberalization mechanism—you open your markets in return for my opening mine—that has been the basis for previous successes in the trading system.
To achieve this reciprocity, first and foremost, the world should declare that the Doha Round is dead and place a wider range of issues on the agenda. China’s trading partners remain concerned by Beijing’s exchange rate policies, as well as the protection and discrimination that stem from China’s state capitalism. China and other countries have an interest in ensuring that their exports are not subject to antidumping and trade restrictions, uncertainty from investment regulations, and international rules on subsidies in relation to climate change.
Everyone has an interest in preventing export protectionism, liberalizing trade in goods and services, and opening government procurement markets. To achieve these goals, Mattoo and Subramanian (2012a) call for a new China Round of multilateral negotiations focused on some of these issues, with participation (initially) by a core group or critical mass of large trading countries (Low 2012).
Any new initiative will have to break from the past in one key respect. Countries in the West have been the drivers of past trade negotiations. China and the other big emerging market countries must now take the lead in negotiating further multilateral liberalization (the alternative, an orderly retreat from globalization, is explored with some skepticism in box 5.2). If they do not, there is the risk that mega-regional agreements will spread, which would be detrimental to the excluded larger emerging markets.
Box 5.2 Is an Orderly Retreat from Globalization Possible?
In discussing the challenges of globalization, the possibility of a retreat from it must not be ignored. A meaningful and consequential retreat would have to be led by the major trading powers, especially the United States, Europe, and China. If it is sparked by political or security conflicts, there can by definition be no orderly retreat.
One recent historical did represent a retreat from globalization. Although not close to the severity of protectionism seen during the 1920s and 1930s, the 1980s experience of U.S.–Japan trade relations is nevertheless instructive. In the wake of the recessions in the early 1980s and the appreciation of the dollar through 1985, the United States became more protectionist (Destler 1992). This protectionism took several forms. Some actions were consistent with the letter if not the spirit of international rules (for example, recourse to antidumping and countervailing duties). Other actions clearly violated the rules (for example, getting Japan to impose voluntary export restraints) or involved the threat of illegal trade sanctions to persuade/coerce Japan to open up its own market. This experience suggests that it will be difficult to craft rules ex ante that bind the very players that have the power to violate or disregard them in the very circumstances that create the greatest incentives to do so.
6. Concluding Thoughts on the Future of Trade Integration and Cooperation
Can and will the ongoing process of hyperglobalization of goods and services continue? Or, to use Keynes’ evocative phrase, might there be “serpents to the paradise” of the ongoing process of hyperglobalization?
Why Optimism about Globalization?
Although trade has been rising rapidly, the process is less than half complete. On a value-added basis, the world trade-to-GDP ratio is about 25 percent. but a simple frictionless gravity model predicts that the theoretical maximum should be substantially greater.37 At least three forces will drive globalization toward and sustain it at higher levels: economic convergence; technology; and interests, ideas, and institutions.
Economic convergence
As more countries continue to grow and to grow more rapidly, trade will increase, as figure 2.4 illustrates. Clearly, the pace of globalization will be affected by the pace of convergence. If Rodrik’s more sober assessment prevails, the pace of globalization may slow, but it will not be reversed. If the pace described in table 2.1 is sustained, so, too, will the ongoing hyperglobalization.
Technology
Predicting the pace of technological progress is impossible. Revolutions in transportation, and then in information and communication technologies, have driven trade globalization. Even if the pace of new discoveries slows, there is scope for the spread of existing technologies, both directly and embodied in FDI. Mobile telephony, Internet usage, and connectivity are still far from universal (Aker and Mbiti 2010).
37 Recall that this model suggests that the ratio of world trade-to-GDP should be 1 minus the sum of the squared shares of countries in world output. With convergence and a sufficiently large number of countries, the sum of squared shares should converge to 0, and the ratio of world trade to GDP should converge to 1.
Interests, ideas, and institutions
Bhagwati (1988) identifies a set of factors he calls the three I’s: interests, ideas, and institutions. The very fact of hyperglobalization deepens the enmeshing of interests across countries, people, and companies. In the current phase, the additional reinforcing factor relates to the phenomenon of criss-crossing globalization discussed earlier.
One of the widely noted features of the global financial crisis was the drop in trade that exceeded the decline in the aftermath of the Great Depression. Yet unlike in the past, the world did not collapse into a protectionist spiral.38 One reason why this collapse did not occur was that countries, no longer tied to the gold standard or otherwise straitjacketed, had broader macroeconomic policy options. Another reason was that the vertical integration of production via supply chains made it difficult and undesirable for countries to impose barriers that would undermine these chains and hence trading opportunities.
The supply chain phenomenon has a broader counterpart. Not only goods moving back are and forth—capital flows are, too. FDI flows no longer just flow downhill from rich to poor countries. Brazil, China, and India are all becoming large exporters of FDI. As capital relocates internationally, the political economy of protectionism also changes. U.S. firms in China have lobbied strongly against U.S. trade action against China. India can now less afford to repel FDI if Indian companies at the same time seek to operate in and from foreign markets (Mattoo and Subramanian 2010).
The recent crises provoked an existential debate about capitalism and finance, but the ideological near-consensus that trade in goods and services as well as FDI should flow relatively unimpeded has not been dented.
38 Global Trade Alert (2012) suggests that there was an upsurge in protectionism after the global financial crises, the quantitative impact of which remains far from clear. Hufbauer and others (2013) document the rise of local content requirements in a number of countries.
Is There Reason to Be Sanguine about Trade?
The cardinal sin of forecasting is to extrapolate the recent past, as Norman Angell, future Nobel Peace Prize winner, did in 1910, when he published The Great Illusion. This pamphlet-turned-book acquired cult status for propagating the view that Europe had become so interlaced economically through trade, credit, and finance that war was impossible. Twentieth century wars would be so economically devastating even to the aggressor that waging one would amount to self-inflicted folly.39
Notwithstanding the five influences discussed above, history’s lesson is that “we cannot be 100 percent certain that the enmeshing of interests will be strong enough to sustain the status quo. Nor is there a cast-iron guarantee that the current ideological embrace of markets as the predominant basis for organizing economic relations will survive the vicissitudes of intellectual fashion and the selective and self-serving interpretations of policymakers. There is tail-side risk (that is, a small, but nontrivial probability of catastrophic outcomes) that interests, ideology, and institutions, both domestic and international, will be the inadequate to the task of preserving the current system. And then there is always the unforeseeable and the irrational. World War I, after all, did happen” (Subramanian 2011, p. 170).
Section 5 discussed the factors that become serpents in the paradise of hyperglobalization. They include prolonged weakness in the West, a serious domestic shock in China that precipitates a retreat there, and the vacuum in international governance. The status quo power is in economic decline, and the rising power will prioritize domestic interests over international responsibilities to a greater degree than previous superpowers, because it is still only a middle-income country. Another unforeseeable factor is the politics and projects of militarism and imperialism (for example, a conflict between China and Japan), which could set back globalization.
Most of the actions that will allow positive influences to prevail over globalization-reversing ones will be at the national level: actions to address economic decline in the West and sustain growth in the Rest, especially China. Collective action should help strengthen the institutional underpinnings of globalization. These actions include ensuring that domestic social insurance mechanisms are not undermined by globalization and bolstering multilateral institutions to prevent conflict between the major trading partners. Greater cooperation on taxes may become necessary to preserve funding for these mechanisms. The world should declare the Doha Round dead in order to move to more meaningful multilateral negotiations to address emerging challenges, including any possible threats from new mega-regional agreements. The rising powers, especially China, will have a key role to play to resuscitate multilateralism.
The open, rules-based trading system has delivered immense benefits for all, especially today’s emerging market economies. Preserving it will ensure that low-income countries can also make successful growth transitions. It is often overlooked that the international trading system has witnessed more successful cooperation, especially between the systemically important countries, than the international financial and monetary system. So cooperation to preserve globalization, even if not in its most hyper current incarnation, is of critical importance. It may also prove less difficult.
39 In the words of Lord Esher, Angell’s most earnest disciple, the inevitable consequences of “commercial disaster, financial ruin, and individual suffering” would be “pregnant with restraining influences.”
Appendix A
Measuring Value-Added Trade
In national account systems, trade is measured in gross terms, meaning that an export from a country is counted at its full value, whether this value was produced in the country or imported in part from another country (via foreign purchases of intermediate goods). It is thus possible to count a good that crosses frontiers at multiple stage of its production several times.
This accounting lies in contrast to the way in which GDP is computed. It is measured in terms of value added: the value of the intermediates used in production is subtracted from the value of the final good.
This distinction between gross and value-added trade has assumed significance in wake of the ongoing process of the slicing up of the value chain across national boundaries. Slicing up is not a new phenomenon, but its magnitude has accelerated sharply in recent years, increasing the importance of proper measurement. Recent attempts have been made to correct this discrepancy and measure a consistent index of “value-added trade” by linking trade data and input-output tables. The basic idea is to link sources and uses of goods and services to be able to trace to its origin the value-added embodied in an exported good.
Johnson and Noguera (2012) use estimates for 42 countries since 1970; their table 7 is the source of the value-added trade data in figure 2.1 in this paper. They use the concept of value-added exports (VAX), the ratio of value added in the country and exported to total exports. Recent research has refined the understanding of value-added trade by distinguishing various stages of production and trade (Koopman, Wang, and Wei, 2013). In this paper, for reasons of simplicity, we adopt the VAX approach. To calculate the value-added trade data presented in the tables and figures presented in this appendix, we used the publicly available World Input Output Tables (available at http://www.wiod.org/database/iot.htm). These data span 15 years (1995–2009) and include 40 countries (including 27 EU countries and large developed and emerging market economies as well as a “rest of the world” aggregate), which represent 85–90 percent of global GDP.
We faithfully follow the methodology described in Johnson and Noguera (2012) to obtain a measure of bilateral exports in terms of both domestic and foreign value added. These exports are combined in various ways to derive the numbers used in the appendix figures and tables.
The caveat is that without firm-level data, one has to make the assumption that the production function is homogeneous within a sector across exporting and nonexporting firms. This assumption is probably not accurate, as exporters generally differ in size, productivity, and technology. The value-added trade data presented, although improvements over gross trade data, should be seen as first, and necessarily imperfect, approximations to the “real” value-added data.
The World Input Output Table data are based on preliminary estimates that have since been revised, creating creates discrepancies for China in 2008 and 2009 and for India to a lesser extent. Data for the two years should therefore be used with caution (the problems with these years led us to use 2007 as the last year in the appendix tables).
Table A.1 Mega-exporters, Based on Value-Added Trade
(percent)
Country/measure | Trade as a share of GDP | Overtrading, controlling for size | Overtrading, controlling for size and per capita GDP | Overtrading, controlling for size and per capita GDP and oil/small country dummies |
---|---|---|---|---|
Japan (1995) (36 countries in sample) | ||||
Gross exports | 9.2 | –55.8*** | –53.8*** | –52.8*** |
Value-add exports | 8.5 | –46.9*** | –45.5*** | –44.3** |
China (2007) (35 countries in sample) | ||||
Gross exports | 37.9 | 160.7*** | 155.0*** | 161.0*** |
Value-add exports | 27.7 | 103.2*** | 102.1*** | 109.6*** |
Sources: Authors, based on data from World Input-Output Tables and Penn World Tables 7.1.
Note: See note to table 2.3; regressions are similar but use value-added exports and a restricted sample for comparability. * = significant at the 10 percent level, ** = significant at the 5 percent level, *** = significant at the 1 percent level.
Table A.2 China Shock Based on Gross and Value-Added Imports, 1995–2007
Figure A.1 Gross and Value-Added Imports by the United States as Share of Consumption, 1995–2009
Figure A.2 Relative Income Level of Exporters to the European Union, Japan, and the United States, Based on Value-Added Imports, 1995–2010
Figure A.3 Relative Income Level of Exporters to the European Union, Japan, and the United States, Based on Value-Added Imports at Fixed Weights, 1980–2010
References
- Aker, J., and I. Mbiti. 2010. “Mobile Phones and Economic Development in Africa.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 24 (3): 207–32.
- AMECO (Annual Macroeconomic Database). Various years. European Commission. http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/ameco/user/serie/SelectSerie.cfm.
- Anderson, J.A. 2011. “The Gravity Model.” Annual Review of Economics 3 (1): 133–60.
- Autor, D., D. Dorn, and G.H. Hanson. 2013. “The China Syndrome: Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States.” American Economic Review.
- Baier, S.L., and J. H. Bergstrand. 2001. “The Growth of World Trade: Tariffs, Transport Costs, and Income Similarity.” Journal of International Economics 53 (1): 1–27.
- Bairoch, P. 1996. “Globalization, Myths and Realities: One Century of External Trade and Foreign Investment.” In States against Markets: The Limits of Globalisation, ed. R. Boyer and D. Drache, 173–92. London: Routledge.
- Baldwin, R., and S. Evenett. 2009. The Collapse of Global Trade, Murky Protectionism and the Crisis: Recommendations for the G20. E-book. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.
- Baldwin, R. 2011a. “Trade and Industrialisation after Globalisation’s 2nd Unbundling: How Building and Joining a Supply Chain Are Different and Why It Matters.” Working Paper17716, National Bureau of Economic Research, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
- ———. 2011b, “21st Century Regionalism: Filling the Gap between 21st Century Trade and 20th Century Trade Rules.” Policy Insight No. 56, Center for Economic Policy Research Policy, Washington, DC.
- ———. 2012. “WTO 2.0: Global Governance of Supply-Chain Trade.” Policy Insight No. 64, Center for Economic Policy Research Policy, Washington, DC.
- Banerjee, A., and E. Duflo. 2011. Poor Economics. A Radical Rethinking of the Way to Fight Global Poverty. New York: Public Affairs.
- Bergsten, C F., and J.E. Gagnon. 2012. “Currency Manipulation, the US Economy, and the Global Economic Order.” Policy Brief 12-25, Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC.
- Bernanke, B. 2005. “The Global Saving Glut and the US Current Account Deficit.” Sandridge Lecture, Virginia Association of Economics, Richmond, Virginia, March 10.
- ———. 2007. “Global Imbalances: Recent Developments and Prospects.” Bundesbank Lecture, Berlin, September 11.
- Bernanke, B., C. Bertaut, L. DeMarco, and S. Kamin. 2011. “International Capital Flows and the Return to Safe Assets in the United States, 2003–2007.” FRB International Finance Discussion Paper 1014, Federal Reserve Board, Washington, DC.
- Bhagwati, J. 1988. Protectionism. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
- Blinder, A.S. 2009. “How Many US Jobs Might Be Offshorable?” World Economics 10 (2): 41.
- Borchert, I., B. Gootiiz, and A. Mattoo. 2012. “Policy Barriers to International Trade in Services: Evidence from a New Database.” Policy Research Working Paper 6109, World Bank, Washington, DC.
- Borchert, I., B. Gootiiz, A. Goswami, and A. Mattoo. 2012. “Landlocked or Policy Locked? How Services Trade Protection Deepens Economic Isolation.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 5942, Washington, DC.
- Brülhart, M. 2009. “An Account of Global Intra-industry Trade, 1962–2006.” World Economy 32 (3): 401–59.
- Carpenter, T., and A. Lendle. 2011. “How Preferential Is World Trade?” CTEI Working Paper, Centre for Trade and Economic Integration, The Graduate Institute, Ecole des Hautes Etudes, Geneva.
- Cline, W.R. 2005. The United States as a Debtor Nation. Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC.
- Destler, I.M. 1992. American Trade Politics, 2nd. ed. New York: New York University Press.
- Dooley, M.P., D. Folkerts-Landau, and P. Garber. 2003. “An Essay on the Revived Bretton Woods System.” NBER Working Paper 9971, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
- Dunning, J.H. 1983. “Changes in the Level and Structure of International Production: The Last One Hundred Years.” In The Growth of International Business, ed. M. Casson. London: Allen and Unwin.
- Edwards, L., and R.Z. Lawrence. 2013. Rising Tide: Is Growth in Emerging Economies Good for the United States? Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC.
- Eichengreen, B., and D. Irwin. 2009. “The Protectionist Temptation: Lessons from the Great Depression for Today.” Vox-EU. http://www.voxeu.org/article/protectionist-temptation-lessons-great-depression-today.
- Frieden, J.A. 2006. Global Capitalism: Its fall and Rise in the Twentieth Century. New York: WW Norton.
- Global Trade Report. 2012. Débâcle: The 11th GTA Report on Protectionism. Centre for Economic Policy Research, London.
- Goldstein, M. 2009. “A Grand Bargain for the London G20 Summit: Insurance and Obeying the Rules.” VoxEU. http://www.voxeu.org/article/grand-bargain-london-g20-summit.
- Haldane, A. 2010. “The $100 Billion Question.” Speech to Institute of Regulation and Risk, Hong Kong, March.
- Hanson, G.H. 2012. “The Rise of Middle Kingdoms: Emerging Economies in Global Trade.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 26 (2): 41–63.
- Haskins, R., J. Isaacs, J., and I. Sawhill, I. 2008. “Getting Ahead or Losing Ground: Economic Mobility in America.” Brookings Institution, Washington, DC.
- Helpman, E., and P.R. Krugman. 1985. Market Structure and Foreign Trade: Increasing Returns, Imperfect Competition, and the International Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
- Hoekman, B. 2013. Enabling Trade: Valuing Growth Opportunities. World Economic Forum report, Davos, Switzerland.
- Hoekman, B., and A. Nicita. 2011. “Trade Policy, Trade Costs, and Developing Country Trade.” World Development 39 (12): 2069–79.
- Hufbauer, G.C., J. J. Schott, M. Vieiro, and E. Wada. 2013. “Local Content Requirements: A Global Problem.” Peterson Institute for International Economics Working Paper, Washington, DC.
- Hummels, D. 2007. “Transportation Costs and International Trade in the Second Era of Globalization.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 21 (3): 131–54.
- Hummels, D.L., J. Ishii, and K.M. Yi. 2001. “The Nature and Growth of Vertical Specialization in World Trade.” Journal of International Economics 54 (1): 75–96.
- International Economic Law and Policy Blog. 2008. Export Restrictions. worldtradelaw.typepad.com/ielpblog.
- IMF (International Monetary Fund). Various years. Direction of Trade Statistics. Washington, DC.
- Irwin, D.A. 2011. Trade Policy Disaster: Lessons from the 1930s. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
- Johnson, R.C., and G. Noguera. 2012. “Fragmentation and Trade in Value Added over Four Decades.” NBER Working Paper 18186. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
- Johnson, S., and J. Kwak. 2010. 13 Bankers: The Wall Street Takeover and the Next Financial Meltdown. New York: Vintage Books.
- Keynes, J.M. 1920. The Economics Consequences of the Peace. New York: Harcourt-Brace.
- Klasing, M., and P. Milionis. 2012. “Reassessing the Evolution of World Trade, 1870–1949.” University of Groningen Working Paper, SSRN 2087678, Groningen, the Netherlands.
- Koopman R., Z. Wang, and S.-J. Wei. 2013. “Tracing Value-Added and Double Counting in Gross Exports.” American Economic Review
- Krugman, P. 1995. “Growing World Trade: Causes and Consequences.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 327–77.
- ———. 2008. “Trade and Wages, Reconsidered.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 103–54.
- ———. 2010. “Chinese Currency Discussion.” http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2010/03/17/chinese-currency-discussion.
- Lawrence, R. 1996. Regionalism, Multilateralism and Deeper Integration. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
- Lieberthal, K., and J. Wang. 2012. “Addressing US-China Strategic Distrust.” Brookings Institution, Washington, DC.
- Low, P. 2012. “The TPP in a Multilateral World.” In The Trans-Pacific Partnership. A Quest for a Twenty-First Century Trade Agreement, ed. C.L. Lim, D.K. Elms, and P. Low, 299–31. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
- Luce, E. 2010. “The Crisis of Middle-Class America.” Financial Times, July 30.
- Mattoo, A., and A. Subramanian. 2009. “Currency Undervaluation and Sovereign Wealth Funds: A New Role for the World Trade Organization.” World Economy 32 (8): 1135–64.
- ———. 2010. “Criss-Crossing Globalization: Uphill Flows of Skill-Intensive Goods and Foreign Direct Investment.” Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics 2009. Global: People, Politics, and Globalization. Washington, DC: World Bank.
- ———. 2012a. “China and the World Trading System.” World Economy 35 (12): 1733–71.
- ———. 2012b. Greenprint: A New Approach to Cooperation on Climate Change. Center for Global Development, Washington, DC.
- ———. 2013. “Four Changes to Trade Rules on Climate Change.” Policy Brief, Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC.
- Mattoo, A., P. Mishra, and A. Subramanian. 2012. “Spillover Effects of Exchange Rates: A Study of the Renminbi.” Working Paper 12-4, Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC.
- Melitz, M.J., and D. Trefler. 2012. “Gains from Trade when Firms Matter.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 26 (2): 91–118.
- Mussa, M. 2007. “IMF Surveillance over China’s Exchange Rate Policy.” In Debating China’s Exchange Rate Policy, ed. M. Goldstein and N. Lardy. pp. 279–339. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.
- OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). Various years. OECD Statistics. Paris. http://stats.oecd.org/.
- O’Rourke, K.H., and J.G. Williamson. 1999. Globalization and History: The Evolution of a Nineteenth-Century Atlantic Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
- Penn World Tables. Penn World Table 7.1.https://pwt.sas.upenn.edu/php_site/pwt71/pwt71_form.php.
- Pew Center. 2010. “Americans Are of Two Minds on Trade. More Trade, Mostly Good; Free Trade Pacts, Not So.” http://www.pewresearch.org/2010/11/09/americans-are-of-two-minds-on-trade/.
- Piketty, T., and E. Saez. 2003. “Income Inequality in the United States, 1913–1998.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118 (1): 1–41.
- Rodrik, D. 1998. “Why Do More Open Economies Have Bigger Governments?” Journal of Political Economy 106 (5): 997–1032.
- ———. 2004. Has Globalization Gone Too Far? Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC.
- Ruggie, J.G. 1998. Constructing the World Polity. London: Routledge.
- Samuelson, P.A. 2004. “Where Ricardo and Mill Rebut and Confirm Arguments of Mainstream Economists Supporting Globalization.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 18 (3): 135–46.
- Spence, M., and S. Hlatshwayo. 2012. “The Evolving Structure of the American Economy and the Employment Challenge.” Comparative Economic Studies 54 (4): 703–38.
- Subramanian, A. 2011. Eclipse: Living in the Shadow of China’s Economic Dominance. Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC.
- Summers, L. 2008a. “America Needs to Make a New Case for Trade.” Financial Times, April 27
- ———. 2008b. “A Strategy to Promote Healthy Globalization.” Financial Times, May 4.
- Trefler, D. 1993. “Trade Liberalization and the Theory of Endogenous Protection: An Econometric Study of U.S. Import Policy.” Journal of Political Economy 101 (1): 138–60.
- UN (United Nations). Various years. National Account Statistics. New York.
- UNCTAD (United Nation Conference on Trade and Development). Various years. UnctadStat. http://unctadstat.unctad.org/ReportFolders/reportFolders.aspx?sCS_referer=&sCS_ChosenLang=en
- ———. 2010. Global Investment Trends Monitor: Global and Regional FDI Trends in 2009.Geneva. http://www.unctad.org/en/docs/webdiaeia20101_en.pdf.
- U.S. Census Bureau. Various years. www.census.gov
- USITC (United States International Trade Commission). 2011. The Economic Effects of Significant U.S. Import Restraints: Seventh Update. Investigation No. 332-325, USITC Publication 4253, Washington, DC.
- Williamson, J.H. 2011. “Getting Surplus Countries to Adjust.” Policy Brief 11-1, Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC.
- Wolf, M. 2010. “China and Germany Unite to Impose Global Deflation.” Financial Times, March 16.
- World Bank. 2009. Global Economic Prospects 2009: Commodities at the Crossroads. Washington, DC: World Bank.
- ———. 2011. Data on Trade and Import Barriers. Washington, DC. http://econ.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/EXTRESEARCH/0,,contentMDK:21051044~pagePK:64214825~piPK:64214943~theSitePK:469382,00.html.
- ———. 2012. China 2030: Building a Modern, Harmonious, and Creative Society. Washington, DC: World Bank.
- ———. Various years. World Development Indicators. Washington, DC: World Bank.
- WIOD, World Input-Output Tables and International Supply and Use Tables. http://www.wiod.org/database/iot.htm.
- WTO (World Trade Organization). 2011. The WTO and Reciprocal Preferential Trading Agreements. Geneva.
- ———. 2013. The Shaping Factors of World Trade over the Next Decade. Geneva.
- Yao, Y. 2013. “America’s Pivot to Asia Will Provoke China.” Financial Times, February 12. http://blogs.ft.com/the-a-list/2013/02/12/americas-pivot-to-asia-will-provoke-china/#axzz2QTlHlbKQ.
- Zaman, H., C. Delgado, D. Mitchell, and A. Revenga. 2008. Rising Food Prices. Are There Right Policy Choices? World Bank Institute, Washington, DC.